The Future of Academic Publishing




(1)
Faculty of Law, Ruhr University of Bochum, Bochum, Germany

 



Despite some countervailing effects of a shift from the CA to the OA model—which have to be taken into account closely in the process of reconceptualizing the predominant business model in academic publishing—there is one important conclusion from our analysis and the overall research on this intriguing topic: Open access should be the future of academic publishing (Finch 2012).

In the public debate several policy implications are discussed between the different stakeholders and advocates of the OA regime, ranging from an abolishment of copyright to the introduction of particular copyright exceptions for research purposes. Also several alternative and complementary approaches to a reform of copyright are forwarded in the debate. This chapter shall investigate the optimal policy mix for the future of academic publishing. In Sect. 5.1, we will further elaborate on the policy implications of an OA regime as the proposed future of academic publishing. We will start with an investigation for a reform of copyright. Different approaches to a reform of copyright are analyzed. Furthermore, references are made regarding the conclusions reached from our analysis of the international political economy of the overall system in the previous section. Thereafter, we will further assess the ability of alternative and complementary approaches to foster a culture of OA in academia. In Sect. 5.2, we will point to some limitations of our analysis and offer caveat for further research on some intriguing questions in shaping the future of academic publishing.


5.1 Policy Implications


In assessing the ability of a variety of different policies and seeking an optimal mix of these policies for the promotion of OA publishing needs a benchmark to which these policies should be weighted against. In this regard, primarily two features or benchmarks should create a baseline for our policy analysis. First and foremost, a policy should be feasible. This includes both legal as well as political feasibility. Accordingly, it should be carefully assessed whether certain policy steps are realizable or infringe certain legal rules that are granted e.g. by international conventions. Moreover, political feasibility shall consider possible political forces such as lobbying that may prohibit certain policy interventions.1 Second, a policy should be reasonable. This feature further investigates the effectiveness of a certain policy in reaching the objectives or solving the trade-off of an optimal publishing model. Recalling the reward structure of scientific research and understanding why scientists do science leaves us with primarily two objectives: On the one hand, scholars should receive credit for their writings according to their impact for the advancement of science or knowledge. The performance of a scientist is measured by the sum of academic works weighed with their impact, i.e. the reputation/impact factor that is assigned to a particular journal. The environment for individual career advancement is competitive.2 On the other hand, new findings/research output should be made available immediately and at minimal costs to enable for priority to discovery and maximize knowledge diffusion.3 In this regard, we will revert to some of the countervailing effects that we concluded from our analysis in Chap. 4, which need careful considerations in specifying adequate policy measurements.


5.1.1 Reform of Copyright


Obviously, as researchers are rather motivated by means of reputation and peer recognition than financial gains from selling their academic works, one might ask why copyright protection for academic works is at all needed. In an intriguing paper, Shavell (2010) investigates this question on whether an abolishment of copyright for academic works is reasonable. As discussed before, he argues as follows: (1) scientists seek reputation which is increasing in readership, (2) readership is higher under open access and hence scholarly esteem, (3) the publication costs due to a shift towards the “author-pays” principle under open access will be covered by most universities, and (4) there are several reasons why a shift towards an open access publishing model will not be smooth without legislative steps (Shavell 2010; Eger and Scheufen 2012b, pp. 54–55). In our analysis we have pointed to several countervailing effects of a shift towards an universal OA regime by reconsidering primarily argument (3) of the Shavell model. The question now is whether a removal of copyright protection for academic works—which necessarily forces an universal OA regime—is feasible and reasonable from a law and economics perspective. In this regard, a policy (law) abolishing copyright for academic works may already fail the feasibility benchmark. The primer reason for the infeasibility of an abolishment of copyright is of legal nature. Peukert (2013b) highlights that an abolishment of copyright is eventually incompatible with the Berne convention. Accordingly, Art. 2 (1) of the Berne convention expands copyright protection to all creations in literature, scientific research and art (Hansen 2005, p. 382). It is this lack in “legal feasibility” that may also explain why with the “Public Access to Science Act” a similar policy attempt failed in US congress in 2003 (Hansen 2005, p. 382; Peukert 2013b, p. 18).4 Shavell (2010) simply omits this fundamental insight by only mentioning in a footnote that “Paul Goldstein has suggested to [him] that elimination of copyright for academic works could lead to conflict with the obligations of the United States under the TRIPS Agreement” (Shavell 2010, p. 339).5 Beyond the feasibility requirement there are also several reasons why an abolishment of copyright is also not reasonable from an economics perspective. First and foremost, our analysis has shown that OA may not necessarily increase the effort incentives of researchers due to the rent-seeking motive in the publishing game. Furthermore, there are several other authors who have been pointing to countervailing effects of copyright removal (McCabe and Snyder 2004, 2005; Mueller-Langer and Watt 2010, 2012).6 Most importantly, copyright may have important implications for the reputation of journals and hence scholarly esteem in the first place. If we believe in this argument, a removal of copyright would necessarily harm the ability of researchers to receive credit for their writings. As a consequence, there are several reasons—also beyond its incompatibility with international law—why an abolishment of copyright (forced OA) is not an appropriate means to promote OA publishing. However, a reform limiting the scope of copyright (i.e. exceptions and limitations of copyright protection) may be feasible and reasonable in this regard.

One option that seeks to limit the scope of copyright protection to accommodate the needs of science is the introduction of a so called “inalienable right of secondary publication”.7 Such an “inalienable right of secondary publication” would give the author more bargaining power in the contractual relationships with publishers. As we have seen, publishers typically ask for a transfer of an exclusive commercial right from the author. Nowadays, most of the journal publishers’ copyright agreements do allow for some form of self-archiving by the author. Nevertheless, it is still to the publisher to decide whether an author may also deposit a copy (pre- or post-print) of her own work in an online repository. An “inalienable right of secondary publication” would give the author the freedom to deposit a pre- and/or post-print version of her journal publication. The fact that the German parliament (Deutscher Bundestag) has enacted a bill for an “inalienable right of secondary publication” on 27 June 2013 shows that a modification of copyright in this regard is generally a feasible option for strengthening the position of authors and indirectly for promoting OA publishing. Nevertheless, the feasibility of the implementation of such an “inalienable right of secondary publication” as a general exception of copyright will decisively depend on the ability of national states to achieve collective action. Most importantly, a unilateral step forward by a single nation carries the risk of weakening both authors’ and publishers’ position in the international competition of science. As discussed in Sect. 4.​2, a reform process that forces a deliberalisation of the international copyright framework as codified under Art. 13 of the TRIPS agreement and Art. 10 of the WIPO Copyright Treaty is required for harmonizing the rules for limiting the scope of copyright and setting equal conditions in the competition of authors in the international publishing game. With regard to the reasonability of an “inalienable right of secondary publication” our assessment will depend on the specific design of the copyright exception. First and foremost, an “inalienable right of secondary publication” would give the author the freedom for reuse of her own published articles without any requirement clause. Accordingly, there is no reason to believe that such a policy could interfere with the researcher’s “freedom to publish” and could hence restrict the researcher in her ability to receive credit.8 However, a unilateral solution where, for instance, only German authors enjoy the freedom for secondary publication could easily generate the opposite effect. That is, publishers could indirectly circumvent such rules in the selection of authors. Obviously, a disputatious argument, but one that should be considered in a truly global science community.9 Second, as the “inalienable right of secondary publication” does not impose any further conditions or requirements for authors to provide OA to their works, it may be limited in achieving the actual goal of OA—immediate and unrestricted access to scientific knowledge. In this regard, a combination of different policies may be necessary. A possible instrument may be to combine an “inalienable right of secondary publication” with a contractual requirement imposed by funding agencies.


5.1.2 Alternatives and Complementary Approaches


A complementary approach to a reform of copyright is to reach contractual commitment among researchers to deposit a copy of their un-/published paper in an institutional or subject based repository. We have already discussed the various opportunities that the government and funding agencies have to contractually regulate OA to publicly funded research. We have seen that in fact a growing amount of countries and several large funding agencies have introduced some form of OA policy that requires OA to publicly-funded research.10 This suggests that OA mandates—i.e. a contractual commitment of the author to provide OA to her publicly-funded research—may be a feasible policy option to foster an unrestricted access to scientific knowledge. A frequently raised concern against such contractual requirements is the argument of academic freedom or particularly the constitutionally guaranteed freedom of publication. In this regard, a group of researchers among the literary scholar Roland Reuß—that became known as the “Heidelberger Appell”—have raised such concerns.11 Taking account of these concerns, an assessment of OA mandates from both feasibility and reasonability perspectives will decisively depend on the design of such mandates. In this context, both roads of OA—i.e. the gold road (OA journals) and the green road (self-archiving or repositories)—provide options for such mandates. Obviously, a policy mandating authors to publish in OA journals only would necessarily undermine the freedom to publish and would likely forward more protest from both researchers and publishers. Not only that such a “gold mandate” would be against the law,12 there would also be strong arguments against it from an economics perspective. We have seen that a policy should allow for a balancing of both sides, ensuring that researchers receive adequate credit for their writings and maximize knowledge diffusion at minimal costs. Accordingly, a commitment that would bind the author to publish in OA journals would—given the prevailing competitive advantage of established CA journals in terms of impact—force OA publications at the costs of lower impact/credit for authors who received such funding. Authors without such contractual constraints—for example due to private funding or other means that offer her freedom to publish—would necessarily have an advantage. That is, there are many arguments why a “gold mandate” would neither fulfil the feasibility nor the reasonability benchmark. However, our conclusions may be different when looking at the latter form of OA mandate—the “green mandate”, i.e. a request or requirement to provide OA to publicly funded research by means of repositories. In this context, the “academic freedom” or “freedom to publish” argument immediately looses weight. The reason is easy to grasp: the “green mandate” leaves it to the author where to publish her works, but asks for a self-archiving of her works after a certain period of time (embargo period). The reasonability of a “green mandate”, however, will decisively depend upon the design and definition of an OA policy for funding agencies.13 Obviously, an OA request or encouragement to self-archive a pre- or post-print version of a paper seems little promising for reaching a sufficient level of OA. In fact, with the “alliance of scientific organizations” in Germany many attempts were made to encourage researchers to deposit a copy of their work in both subject-based and institutionally based repositories. In Sect. 3.​2 we highlighted the “Max Planck Digital Library” (MPDL) which provides an online platform for the exchange of publications by affiliated authors. The wording of the MPG OA policy that “calls upon its academic staff to observe the principle of public availability of basic research” (MPG OA policy)14 already reveals its non-binding character. Not surprisingly, Eger et al. (2013) find that less than 20 % of the 2,151 respondents of their survey show experiences with self-archiving—with large differences between the disciplines.15 Consequently, a simple request that asks authors for self-archiving is little promising. The second OA policy option for funding agencies are OA mandates that explicitly require green OA as a contractual condition for the receipt of funding. In this regard, we already discussed different types of mandates and showed that only rights-retention mandates may guarantee that academic works do not remain non-OA.16 In this context, the funding agencies require to retain a non-exclusive right to authorize OA throughout self-archiving platforms (Suber 2012, p. 80). In general, this form of OA mandate seems promising as it may provide with an effective tool to enhance free online availability of publicly funded research without interfering with the researcher’s “freedom to publish”. Nevertheless, the particular design and means by which such a rights-retention mandate is enforceable may be subject to debate. This debate may involve two general questions. On the one hand, a right retention may be reached by different means. Suber (2012) highlights the Harvard approach which pioneered this approach for universities. Here, the “faculty members vote to give the university a standing nonexclusive right […] to make their future work OA through the institutional repository” (Suber 2012, p. 80) but with the flexibility “to opt out of the grant of permission to the university, but not out of the deposit requirement” (Suber 2012, p. 80). Another means may consider the option to require OA by copyright legislation. We have already discussed the option of an “inalienable right of secondary publication” that gives the author more bargaining power in the contractual relationship with journal publishers. In this regard, both policies (a right-retention mandate by funding agencies and an inalienable right of secondary publication by copyright legislation) may complement one another. On the other hand, the specific design of such a mandate involves several dimensions. The first dimension may be the length of the embargo period which trades off the need to offer enough incentives for publishers to provide the necessary publishing services and the costs of banning an OA for a certain period after publication. Whether the embargo period should be 6 or 12 months after publication may then depend on many aspects and may hence differ between disciplines and countries.17 Second, it will be debatable how to ensure that authors follow the requirement to provide OA to their publicly funded works. Here, Stodden (2009) proposes the Reproducible Research Standard (RRS) as a promising solution for both to ensure attribution and facilitate the sharing of academic works. Other approaches revert to the option to require a deposit of an electronic version at the national library which would then provide OA to all the works.18 Third, the type or form of the work that is deposited. No doubt, an effective OA mandate would have to assure that a final version of the paper (including all changes from revisions) is made available. Other than that would leave us with an insufficient substitute for the original. Obviously, the shape of such a policy leaves us with enough caveat for further research to not only ensure the feasibility of an OA mandate for publicly funded research, but also to guarantee an effective policy framework.

Furthermore, several authors have advocated that scientific societies and universities should launch new OA journals and should hence act as a counterbalance to the dominance of commercial publishers. A closer look at the history of the academic journal publishing market actually shows that both academic societies and universities can look back on a great tradition in publishing academic journals. We have seen that the first journal titles were launched throughout the sole initiative of academic association. Commercial publishers started to enter the market for academic publishing after the second world war. The dominance of commercial publishers—with all the consequences we are currently facing (serial crisis)—is a rather new phenomenon. The vision in this process is easy to grasp: If academic societies and universities would become more active as publishers of academic journals they could create a balance weight against the prevailing dominance of commercial publishers. Two arguments are broad forward in the literature to believe that this approach could be a feasible solution. First and foremost, several universities and academic societies have experiences in publishing journals.19 A famous example is the Oxford University Press as the world’s largest university press. The Oxford University Press currently offers a portfolio of 250 journal titles.20 Second, this particular group has a strong incentive to self-enforce a change in paradigm as the universities, in general, and the university libraries, in particular, are directly affected by the constraints imposed by the serial crisis. There is no reason to believe why universities and/or academic societies are not able to launch new journal titles. However, just like OA journals in general, also these journals will necessarily lack in reputation. As a matter of fact, especially young researchers would be reluctant to publish in these journals as they would provide with a lower credit or impact as compared to well-established commercial publishers. This leaves us with the previously outlined dilemma of OA journals and the question whether the reward structure in academia may be seen as the biggest hurdle in an evolutionary process towards an OA publishing mode.

Thus, far from any exogenous market intervention a new paradigm of OA could be induced from within the system itself. In fact, a closer look at the “OA dilemma” reveals that it originates in the prevailing reward structure, i.e. the ways scholars receive credit for their performance.21 We have seen that the general performance measurement used for assessing the standing of a researcher within her peer group is the impact factor of a journal publication. Rankings are calculated which shall display the performance of individuals or institutions based on a weighted sum of all publications, where the impact factor reflects the weight or quality of a certain publication.22 Nowadays, the tenure procedure has evolved to unilaterally focus on (journal)23 publications only and has induced an environment that is typically referred to as the “publish or perish” environment of scientific research.24 Several others criticize that a “taste for rankings” paradigm has crowded out the traditional academic notion of a “taste for science”, which emphasizes the relevance of motivational factors like autonomy and peer recognition as opposed to monetary rewards (Osterloh 2013, p. 106; Roach and Sauermann 2010).25 As a matter of fact, it is exactly this “reward system” that may induce a lock-in to the traditional publishing model and may prevent an evolutionary process towards an otherwise superior OA regime. As we have seen in Sect. 3.​1 there is clear empirical evidence for a reputation or impact factor advantage of established CA publishers over OA publishers. Consequently, researchers seem to be locked-in to the weak equilibrium, where especially young researcher will prefer to publish in established CA journals to receive credit for their writings.26 Others have been pointing to this dilemma as the chicken-egg characteristic of a co-existence of both regimes (CA and OA), where publishing in a CA journal dominates any OA attempt and leaves the academic community locked-in to the weak Nash-equilibrium.27 A solution to this “OA dilemma” may be to induce a self-enforcing process towards OA by a reconceptualization of the reward system in academia. This reconceptualization could take many different forms which could be enforced by the community of academics itself. First and foremost, performance measures and tenure procedures should not be unilateraly focused on rankings only. Consciousness about the various problems associated with rankings is important is this regard. Rankings often glorify realities. The position of a journal, institution or researcher in a ranking is easier to assess than the real quality of research. In economics, this is known as the “multiple tasking”-effect (Holmström and Migrom 1991; Ethiraj and Levinthal 2009). In complex systems, like scientific research, goals in terms of performance measurements induce a situation where easy targets (like the position in a ranking) are reached, while the often more important goals (like scientific progress and the diffusion of knowledge) are neglected (Osterloh 2013, p. 105). A solution would be the introduction of additional measurement that directly account for OA features of a researcher’s CV. With other words: The degree to which a researcher provides OA to her research, both in terms of publications in OA journals or self-archiving, should be incorporated when assessing the performance of a researcher. As a consequence, such a performance measure would also account for the positive spill-overs to academia and practice likewise. Second, well-known researchers (e.g. nobelprice laureates) should take a lead in the transition towards more OA publishing. Both OA publications but also editorial positions of renown researchers could serve as a signal of valuation in the academic publishing market.28 Last but not least, the academic society should take advantage of new opportunities like “Open Assessment” for complementing the quality selection process in academic publishing. Obviously, quality selection is important to prevent from the Akerlof lemmons. However, several scholars have been criticizing the ability of the traditional “peer review” model to reach an objective selection process.29 In this context, an Open Assessment similar to customer evaluations in online markets could be used as a means to complement the quality assessment. A broader discussion on the design of the future quality selection process seems necessary.


5.2 A Critical Perspective


Despite the numerous arguments why OA should be the future of academic journal publishing, consciousness is required in the interpretation of the impact of the various policy conclusions. In fact, there are still several questions which remain to be investigated in more detail. Most interestingly, we have seen that the real empirical impact on readership or citations is still questionable.30 While several authors find a significant readership or citation advantage of the OA regime (Eysenbach 2006; Lawrence 2001; Lawrence and Giles 2000), others show that this advantage is declining by 7 % per year and is only 17 % taken all journals together (Davis 2009) or that there is no such advantage of the OA regime (McCabe 2011; Davis 2011; Davis et al. 2008).31 Obviously, as our model stands or falls with the assumption of a (weakly) higher readership under OA, it is important to empirically investigate this intriguing question. Moreover, Mueller-Langer and Watt (2010) have pointed to the fact that it is not the readership alone that drives scholarly esteem, but rather the impact factor of the journal.32 The authors argue that authors would always prefer a more well-esteemed journal with low readership over a less-esteemed journal with higher readership. Consequently, future research should also analyze the impact of quality-adjusted readership on scholarly esteem.

Most importantly, our analysis focusses on the incentives of researchers only. What we have not taken into account is that a regime change will also have important implications for publishers. Obviously, if we do believe that publishers fulfil an important function in the academic publishing market—as an intermediary that provides with several publishing services,33 such as a quality selection (peer review) or editing and typesetting tasks—there needs to be some form of renumeration for publishers. Since an OA regime induces a shift towards the “author pays” model, its impact for publishers will have to be analyzed in detail. In this regard, McCabe and Snyder (2005) have pointed to possible negative effects in form of a quality degradation of OA journals. The reason is simply market power. Even if copyright for academic works were to be removed, established publishers will be able to retain some degree of market power (Mueller-Langer and Watt 2010). Due to the reputation advantage of established publishing houses such as Reed Elsevier or Springer, these publishers will be able to raise prices above marginal costs. As a result, top-tier journals will still be able to make (substantial) profits based on the reputational capital they have accumulated in the past and that necessarily roots in the “taste for rankings” argument as discussed before. The argument by McCabe and Snyder (2005) goes even further. The authors argue that since it is the author who pays per publication, publishers could have a strong incentive to accept more papers for publications as would be socially optimal, with a negative impact for the quality of academic works under OA.34

Last but not least, several questions regarding the impact and the consequences of an (universal) OA regime at the international level will have to be further investigated. We have pointed to several aspects and possible distortions in a truly heterogeneous world. The vision of OA as a means for overcoming the still prevalent digital divide between the developed and the developing world may be a fallacy. In fact, several challenges especially in the international law context remain as the most serious obstacles on the road towards an universal and worldwide OA regime in academic publishing. Further assessments on the (potential) role of OA for developing countries as well as investigations focussing on the international legal framework (primarily copyright law issues) will be necessary to reach reasonable conclusions.

All of the above shows that there is great caveat for further research. Mueller-Langer and Scheufen (2013) highlight several further open questions that go beyond the comparison of CA versus OA publishing. Accordingly, also the consequences of “Hybrid Open Access” (HOA) should be investigated in more detail. In this regard, Mueller-Langer and Watt (2013) point to the possible negative effects of “double dipping”, i.e. publishers are actually charging twice for the same article—the readers for the CA journal version and the author for the open choice option.35 In fact, it is highly questionable whether HOA models follow the “nobel” goal of improving the accessibility of journal content, or whether they provide journal publishers with just another means to price discriminate by segmenting markets between authors and readers. Moreover, also questions concerning OA to data (to improve the replicability of (empirical) research) and online libraries (such as Google Books) offer great caveat for further research.36


Bibliography



Abadie, A., Diamond, A., & Hainmueller, J. (2010). Synthetic control methods for comparative case studies: Estimating the effect of California’s tobacco control program. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 105(490), 493–505.


Acs, Z. J., Audretsch, D. B., & Feldman, M. P. (1994). R&d spillovers and recipient firm size. Review of Economics and Statistics, 76(2), 336–340.


Ahmed, A. (2007). Open access towards bridging the digital divide – Policies and strategies for developing countries. Information Technology for Development, 13(4), 337–361.


Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for ‘lemons’: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.


Akerlof, G. A., Hahn, R., Litan, R. E., Arrow, K. J., Bresnahan, T. F., Buchanan, J. M., Coase, R. H., Cohen, L. R., Friedman, M., Green, J. R., Hazlett, T. W., Hemphill, C. S., Noll, R. G., Schmalensee, R., Shavell, S., Varian, H. R., & Zeckhauser, R. J. (2002). The copyright term extension act of 1998: An economic analysis. AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Brief 02-1. http://​www.​aei-brookings.​org/​admin/​authorpdfs/​page.​php?​id=​16.


Allison, P. D., & Stewart, J. A. (1974). Productivity differences among scientists: Evidence for accumulative advantage. American Sociological Review, 39(4), 596–606.


Andreff, W., & Szymanski, S. (Eds.) (2006). Handbook of the economics of sport. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.


Andreoli-Versbach, P., & Mueller-Langer, F. (2013). Open access to data: An ideal professed but not practiced. RatSWD Working Paper Series No. 215. http://​papers.​ssrn.​com/​sol3/​papers.​cfm?​abstract_​id=​2224146.


Annan, K. (2004). Science for all nations. Science, 303, 925.


Armstrong, C., DeBeer, J., Kawooya, D., Prabhala, A., & Schonwetter, T. (Eds.) (2010). Access to knowledge in Africa: The role of copyright. Claremont: UCT Press.


Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In R. Nelson (Ed.), The rate and direction of inventive activity (pp. 609–624). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.


ARWU (2012). Academic ranking of world universities-2012. http://​www.​shanghairanking.​com/​ARWU2012.​html.


Audretsch, D. B., & Feldman, M. P. (1996). R&d spillovers and the geography of innovation and production. American Economic Review, 86(3), 630–640.


Bakos, Y., & Brynjofsson, E. (1999). Bundling information goods: Pricing, profits and efficiency. Management Science, 45(12), 1613–1630.


Bakos, Y., & Brynjofsson, E. (2000). Bundling and competition on the internet. Marketing Science, 19(1), 63–82.


Bargheer, M. (2006). Open access und universitätsverlage: Auswege aus der publication crisis. In Internetökonomie der Medienbranche. Göttingen: Universitätsverlag Göttingen.


Benkler, Y. (2002). Coase’s penguin, or, linux and the “nature of the firm”. The Yale Law Journal, 112(3), 369–446.


Bently, L. (2010). Introduction to part i: The history of copyright. In L. Bently, U. Suthersanen, & P. Torremans (Eds.), Global copyright. Three hundred years since the statute of anne, from 1709 to cyberspace. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.


Bently, L., & Kretschmer, M. (2013). Primary sources on copyright (1450–1900). www.​copyrighthistory​.​org.


Berger, K. P. (1996). Lex mercatoria doctrine and the unidroit principles of international commercial contracts. Law and Policy in International Business, 28, 943–990.


Bergstrom, T. C. (2001). Free labor for costly journals. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(3), 183–198.


Bergstrom, T. C., Courant, P., & McAffee, R. P. (2013). Big deal contract project. http://​www.​econ.​ucsb.​edu/​~tedb/​Journals/​BundleContracts.​html.


Bergstrom, T. C., & McAffee, R. P. (2013). Summary statistics. http://​www.​hss.​caltech.​edu/​~mcafee/​Journal/​.


Bernius, S. (2010). The impact of open access on the management of scientific knowledge. Online Information Review, 34(4), 583–603.


Bernius, S., & Hanauske, M. (2009). Open access to scientific literature-increasing citations as an incentive for authors to make their publications freely available. In Hawaii International Conference on System Science (HICSS-42).


Bernius, S., Hanauske, M., Koenig, W., & Dugall, B. (2009). Open access models and their implications for the players on the scientific publishing market. Economic Analysis and Policy, 39(1), 103–115.


Besen, S. M. (1986). Private copying, reproduction costs, and the supply of intellectual property. Information Economics and Policy, 2(1), 5–22.


Besen, S. M., & Raskind, L. J. (1989). New technologies and intellectual property: Collectives that collect. Technical report, Rand Corporation, RAND Report No. R-3751-MF.


Besen, S. M., & Raskind, L. J. (1991). An introduction to the law and economics of intellectual property. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 3–27.


Bitton, M. (2012). Implementing the public sector information directive. European Intellectual Property Review, 34(2), 75–86.


Bjoerk, B.-C. (2004). Open access to scientific publications. An analysis of the barriers to change. Information Research, 9(2), 1–17.


Bjoerk, B.-C. (2012). The hybrid model for open access publication of scholarly articles: A failed experiment? Journal of the American Society for Information Science and Technology, 63(8), 1496–1504.


BOAI (2002). Budapest open access initiative. http://​www.​soros.​org/​openaccess/​read.​shtml.


Boldrine, M., & Levine, D. K. (2002). The case against intellectual property. American Economic Review, 92(2), 209–212.


Boldrine, M., & Levine, D. K. (2005). Intellectual property and the efficient allocation of social surplus from creation. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 2(1), 45–67.


Boldrine, M., & Levine, D. K. (2008). Against intellectual property (1st ed.) Cambridge: Cambridge University Press


Börsenverein. (2011). Börsenverein des deutschen buchhandels. stellungnahme zum gesamtkonzept für die informationsinfrastruktur in deutschland (kii-papier), frankfurt.


Bosch, X. (2009). A reflection on open-access, citation counts, and the future of scientific publishing. Archivum Immunologiae et Therapiae Experimentalis, 57(2), 91–93.


Breyer, S. (1970). The uneasy case for copyright: A study of copyright in books, photocopies and computer programs. Harvard Law Review, 84, 281–351.


Brody, T., Harnad, S., & Les, C. (2006). Earlier web usage statistics as predictors of later citation impact. Journal of the Association for Information Science and Technology, 57(8), 1060–1072.


Bundesratsbeschluss. (2013). Mehr open access in der wissenschaft.


Calabresi, G., & Melamed, D. A. (1972). Property rules, liability rules, and inalienability: One view of the cathedral. Harvard Law Review, 85(6), 1089–1128.


Callon, M. (1994). Is science a public good? Fifth Mullins lecture. Science, Technology, and Human Values, 19(4), 395–424.


Campanario, J. M. (1996). Using citation classics to study the incidence of serendipity in scientific discovery. Scientometrics, 20, 4–21.


Campbell. (1994). Campbell, aka skywalker, et al. v. acuff-rose music, inc. (92-1292), 510 U.S. 569. http://​www.​law.​cornell.​edu/​supct/​html/​92-1292.​ZS.​html.


Card, D., & Krueger, A. B. (1994). Minimum wages and employment: A case study of the fast-food industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania. American Economic Review, 84(4), 772–793.


Castells, M. (2000). The information age: The rise of the network society. Oxford: Blackwell.


Cavaleri, P., Keren, M., Ramello, G. B., & Valli, V. (2009). Publishing an e-journal on a shoe string: Is it a sustainable project? Economic Analysis and Policy, 39(1), 89–101.


Cetto, M. A. (2001). The contribution of electronic communication to science – Has it lived up to its promise? In Proceedings to the 2nd ICSU-UNESCO International Conference on Electronic Publishing in Science, 20–23 February, UNESCO House, Paris.


Chang, C. C. (2003). Business models for open access journals publishing. Online Information Review, 30(6), 699–713.


Choi, J. P. (2012). Bundling information goods. In M. Peitz & J. Waldfogel (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of the digital economy (pp. 273–305). Oxford: Oxford University Press.


Christian, G. E. (2008). Open access initiative and the developing world. African Journal of Library Archives and Information Science, 18(2).


Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3(1), 1–44.


Coccia, M. (2006). Economic and social studies of scientific research: Nature and origins. Working Paper CERIS-CNR, 8(7).


Cofer, C. N., & Apply, M. H. (1967). Motivation: Theory and research. New York: Wiley.


Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1989). Innovation and learning: The two faces of r&d. Economic Journal, 99(397), 569–596.


Congleton, R. D., Hillman, A. L., & Konrad, K. (2008). 40 years of research on rent seeking 1. New York: Springer.


Conney-McQuat, S., Busch, S., & Kahn, D. (2010). Open access publishing: A viable solution for society publishers. Learned Publishing, 23(2), 101–105.


Coolidge, H. J., & Lord, R. H. (1932). Archibald cary coolidge: Life and letters. New York: Boston


Cornish, W. (2010). The statute of anne 1709-10: Its historical setting. In L. Bently, U. Suthersanen, & P. Torremans (Eds.), Global copyright. Three hundred years since the statute of anne, from 1709 to cyberspace. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.


Corrigan, R., & Rogers, M. (2005). The economics of copyright. World Economics, 6(3), 153–174.


Craig, I., Plume, A. M., McVeigh, M. E., Pringle, J., & Amin, M. (2007). Do open access articles have greater citation impact? A critical review of the literature. Publishing research consortium. Journal of Informetrics, 1(3), 239–248.


Crane, D. (1965). Scientists at major and minor universities: A study of productivity and recognition. American Sociological Review, 30(5), 699–714.


Csikszentmihalyi, H. (1974). Beyond boredom and anxiety: The experience of play in work and games. San Francisco: Jossey Bass Inc.


Dahlberg, B. (2011). Orphan works problem: Preserving access to the cultural history of disadvantaged groups. Southern California Review of Law and Social Justice 20, 275.


Dalrymple, D. (2003). Scientific knowledge as a global public good: Contributions to innovation and the economy. In J. M. Esanu, & P. F. Uhlir (Eds.), The Role of Scientific and Technical Data and Information in the Public Domain: Proceedings of a Symposium (pp. 35–49). Washington: National Academic Press.


Dasgupta, P., & David, P. A. (1987). Information disclosure and the economics of science and technology. In G. R. Feiwel (Ed.), Arrow and the ascent of modern economic theory. New York: Macmillan Press.


Dasgupta, P., & David, P. A. (1994). Towards a new economics of science. Research Policy, 23(4), 487–521.


David, P. A. (1993). Intellectual property institutions and the panda’s thumb: Patents, copyrights and trade secrets in economic theory and history. In NRC (pp. 19–61).


Davis, P. M. (2009). Author-choice open access publishing in the biological and medical literature. Journal of the American Society for Information Science and Technology, 60(1), 3–8.


Davis, P. M. (2011). Open access, readership, citations: A randomized controlled trial of scientific journal publishing. The FASEB Journal, 25, 1–6.


Davis, P., Lewenstein, B., Simon, D., Booth, J., & Connolly, M. (2008). Open access publishing, article downloads and citations. British Medical Journal, 337, a568.

Only gold members can continue reading. Log In or Register to continue