The New Institutional Economics: Its Start, Its Meaning, Its Prospects




(1)
Department of Economics, Saarland University, Saarbrücken, Germany

 



In slightly changed form reprinted from European Business Organization Law Review, 2005: 6, 161–200. (T.M.C. Asser Institute, The Hague, Netherlands).

I thank John Drobak (Washington University), Jan Kmenta (University of Michigan) and Eirik G. Furubotn (Texas A&M), Valery Katkalo and Natalia Drozdova (Saint-Petersburg State University) for valuable comments. I also thank Rainer Kulms (Editor-in-Chief of EBOR) for his thoughtful suggestions. Any remaining mistakes are the sole responsibility of the author.


This chapter deals with the early stages, meaning, and prospects of a field known under the name of “New Institutional Economics”—a generic term introduced by Williamson (1975, 1). It soon became a standard (or banner) under which a diverse group of economists who shared one common intellectual position assembled: institutions matter, the relationship between institutional structure and economic behaviour requires attention and the determinants of institutions can be analysed with the aid of economic theory.


1 The Evolution of the Field of New Institutional Economics



1.1 Introductory Remarks


That institutions matter for economic performance is an old and inherently plausible intellectual position. However, during the first half of the twentieth century, as the mathematical development of neoclassical theory has progressed and economic models have become increasingly abstract, institutional phenomena have received less and less attention. Thus, institutions play virtually no role at all in what may be regarded as mainstream theory through the 1980s (exemplified by welfare economics and the general equilibrium models of Arrow-Debreu). In other words, it does not matter whether goods and services are exchanged by the use of money or otherwise (Samuelson 1968) or whether production is organized by the price mechanism across markets or within a hierarchically organized firm (Coase 1937) and so forth. Not surprisingly, these extreme views were soon opposed by various strands of a renewed kind of economic institutionalism. Among its outstanding contributors were Coase (1937, 1960), Alchian (1961), Buchanan and Tullock (1962), Olson (1965), Williamson (1971, 1975), and North and Thomas (1973), to name but a few of the pacemakers. Linked with these names are theories such as property rights analysis, the economic analysis of law, public choice theory, constitutional economics, the theory of collective action, transaction cost economics, the principal-agent approach, the theory of relational contracts, and comparative economic systems. Common to all these approaches is that, unlike neoclassical economics, they do not assume the institutional framework as given but make it into the object of research and also seek to consider the implications for economic behaviour of any given institutional arrangements. They do not ask “What would self-interested rational actors do?”, but “How could rational actors be constrained (or constrain themselves) not to pursue their self-interest?” (Miller 1997: 1196). The term “new institutional economics” is used as a generic term by different authors for different combinations of the above-mentioned approaches as well as other fields. In this chapter, we briefly survey the history of the kaleidoscopic use of this term to illustrate the evolution of a new and, as we are convinced, widely applicable bundle of methods of economic research.


1.2 The NIE: The Initial Concept


Oliver Williamson, creator of the term “new institutional economics”, interprets the term rather broadly. He subsumes under the NIE: aspects of mainline micro theory, economic history, the economics of property rights, comparative systems, labour economics, and industrial organization.

The common threads tying these studies together were:

1.

that received micro theory …operates at too high a level of abstraction to permit many important microeconomic phenomena to be addressed in an uncontrived way; and

 

2.

that the study of ‘transaction’ ………. is a core matter and deserves renewed attention.1

 

A few pages later Williamson (1975, 7) describes the principal differences between the earlier literature and his approach as follows:

1.

I am much more concerned than are prior treatments with tracing out the ramifications of bounded rationality;

 

2.

I expressly introduce the notion of opportunism and am interested in the ways that opportunistic behaviour is influenced by economic organization; and

 

3.

I emphasize that it is not uncertainty or small numbers, individually and together, that occasion market failure but it is rather the joining of these factors with bounded rationality on the one hand and opportunism on the other that gives rise to exchange difficulties.

 

In his work, Williamson concentrates on what he later calls transaction cost economics (TCE), which he says is ‘part of new institutional economics’ (Williamson 1985b: 16).

The term NIE seems to have remained largely dormant during the following 5 years or so. However, Leonard Silk mentioned the term in the New York Times of September 24, 1980 as a possible ‘new direction that will gradually draw economists away from their tired repetition of stale and sterile arguments.’2 I myself ‘discovered’ it around the same time on page one of Williamson’s 1975 book. Shortly before, I had become editor of the time-honoured Zeitschrift für gesamte Staatswissenschaft (founded in 1844), at that time still a German language journal on general economics.3 I wanted to ‘internationalize’ the Zeitschrift and looked for a suitable specialty, a niche that remained close to its original field, the “entire science of the state.”4 Public choice and law and economics were already well covered by journals, so the new institutional economics in the sense of Oliver Williamson appeared to be a promising choice. Eirik G. Furubotn was prepared to help me and, without thinking twice, we jointly started a series of international seminars on the NIE with the aim of helping the old Zeitschrift on its feet. That was in 1983. The series became known as “Wallerfangen Conference” and is continued to being organised after my retirement since 1995 by different people and in different locations every year. Papers and discussions are published in the Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE) since 1984.5


1.3 A Brief Interlude: Two Strands of Thought


Among the various approaches to institutional economics, two strands of thought are of interest in relation to the assessment of the NIE. Roughly speaking, they are as follows:

1.

A line of thought from, say, Hume (1739/1940) to Menger (1883), Hayek (1948, 1967), Nelson and Winter (1982), Kirzner (1981), Lewis (1969), Schotter (1981), Axelrod (1984), Binmore (1994, 1998), Greif (1998a, b), Aoki (2001). This line is characterized by self-adjusting processes. Transaction costs play no explanatory role. We call it the ‘invisible-hand’ approach to institutional economics.

 

2.

Another line of thought leads roughly from Knight (1922) and Commons (1934) to Barnard (1938), Hayek (1945), Coase (1937, 1960), Buchanan and Tullock (1962), Olson (1965), Chandler (1962, 1977), Simon (1957, 1987), Alchian (1961), Arrow (1969), Williamson (1975, 1985, 2005), Davis and North (1971), and North (1981, 1990, 2005). In this approach, transaction costs (or information costs) are essential as an explanatory element. For want of a better term, we dub this line the ‘visible-hand approach’ to institutional economics.6

 

The two lines of thought are by no means to be taken as an indication of the historical roots of the NIE. That is a rather complicated issue, which cannot be dealt with here. As for the history of the NIE itself we limit ourselves to the single question, namely how the term ‘new institutional economics’ evolved to a unifying standard.


1.4 The Development of the Term to a Unifying Standard


As mentioned above, the term ‘new institutional economics’ became a more widely-known term around 1980, i.e., 5 years after it had been coined by Williamson (1975: 1). It took another 3 or 4 years until economists used it in the topics or titles of their publications. In EconLit, the term NIE does not appear before 1984, but after that it appears increasingly in titles of journal articles, books, papers in collective volumes and conference publications.7 One simple way to check the pulse of our profession is to read editorial prefaces. Editors are supposedly the brokers (or switchmen) of our profession, so why not apply their judgments as a measuring instrument for the development of the use of the term NIE. Following this strategy, I am going to offer a brief report and evaluation of the editors’ comments to six successively published collective volumes, starting with the first publication in which the term NIE appeared, edited by Furubotn and Richter (1984a), and continuing with the collective volumes edited by Langlois (1986), Nabli and Nugent (1989a, b), Harriss et al. (1995a, b), Drobak and Nye (1997a, b), and Clague (1997).


1.4.1 Which Institutional Economic Fields Do Belong to the NIE?


A first, somewhat simple question is: which specific fields do the editors of the above-mentioned collective volumes consider to be part of the NIE? The answer is:

1.

property rights approach

 

2.

transaction cost approach

 

3.

evolutionary economics

 

4.

constitutional choice

 

5.

collective action theory

 

6.

public choice theory

 

7.

economic contract theory

 

8.

new institutional approach to economic history

 

9.

modern Austrian economics.

 

Table 1.1 shows which fields are ascribed by whom to be parts of the NIE.


Table 1.1
Fields assigned by editors of collective volumes on the NIE



























































































 
Furubotn and Richter (1984a, b)

Langlois (1986)

Nabli and Nugent (1989a, b)

Harriss et al. (1995a, b)

Drobak and Nye (1997a, b)


Transact. costs Ecs.

X

X

X

Xa

X

Χ

Property rights

X

X

X

Xa

X

Χ

Evolut. econ.

Xb

X
       

Public choice political Ecs
     
X

X
 

Contract Th.
   
X
   
X

NIE history
     
X

X
 

Modern Austrian
 
X
       

Constitutional choice

X
         

Collective action
   
X
   
X


aTransaction costs and property rights mentioned implicitly by emphasizing Coase (1937, 1960) and North (1993)

bFurubotn and Richter dropped this field in their subsequent 11 collective volumes (See: http://​www.​uni-saarland.​de/​fak1/​fr12/​albert/​mitarbeiter/​richter/​institut/​waller.​htm)

Obviously, our six collective volumes and their editors do not form a representative sample. However, it sill may not be entirely wrong to assume that Table 1.1 reflects the prevailing view of our profession as regards which fields—and with what weight—should be considered part of the NIE. Property rights and transaction cost economics are quite certainly among. In fact, they were ‘voted’ for by the editors of all six volumes. A distinct minority of editors’ comments (two out of six) name contract theory, collective action, public choice, evolutionary economics, and the new institutional economics approach to history as part of the NIE. The fields of modern Austrian economics and constitutional choice fall far behind with only one vote each. The great weight given to the property rights and transaction cost economics speaks for our earlier presumption that the end piece of the ‘visible-hand’ approach to institutional economics is regarded as belonging to the methods of the new institutional economics.


1.4.2 What Is the Intellectual Connection Between the Fields of the NIE?


A more demanding questions is: what is the common pattern of reasoning or, put differently, what is the intellectual connection between economists who belong to the practitioners of the NIE? In response to this question, we will once again follow the judgment of the editors of the six collective volumes under consideration. Proceeding in chronological order, we will report how they justify their interpretation of the NIE.


1.4.2.1 Furubotn and Richter

Furubotn and Richter (1984a, b) argue that the foundation stones of the NIE consist of the traditional foundation stones of neoclassical theory, namely methodological individualism and the self-interest principle. But while in neoclassical economics the influence of the institutional framework was disregarded completely or specified only in perfunctory a way, the NIE seeks to demonstrate that institutions matter. Beyond this, institutions themselves are regarded as legitimate objects of economic analysis. In other words, the unifying elements of the NIE are its basic methodology and its analytical objects. It does not matter that a number of different approaches are employed in attempting to integrate institutional considerations into economic theory. The authors stress that the study of transactions themselves and of transaction costs is crucial and that another important shift in thinking relates to the way in which property rights structures are perceived. The participation of Armen Alchian, Ronald Coase, Douglass North and Oliver Williamson underlines these judgments.


1.4.2.2 Langlois

Langlois (1986) argues that the NIE consists of a number of identifiable strands. Principal among these are, first of all, evolutionary theory and the modern Austrian school8 as influenced by F. A. Hayek. Historically, Carl Menger might ‘perhaps [have] more claim to be the patron saint of the new institutional economics than any of the original institutionalists’ (Langlois 1986: 5) like John R. Commons, who is quoted by Williamson. Finally, Oliver Williamson, Ronald Coase and Herbert Simon are mentioned (in this order). The Austrian and evolutionary prioritization by Langlois is underlined by conference participants such as Brian J. Loasby, Andrew Schotter, Richard R. Nelson, Gerald P. O’Driscoll, Jr.


1.4.2.3 Nabli and Nugent

Nabli and Nugent (1989a, b) edited a collective volume on the application of the NIE to development economics. While there is as yet no consensus on what is included in the NIE, they find that two broad and general approaches would be salient, ‘namely transaction and information costs, on the one hand, and the theory of collective action on the other’ (Nabli and Nugent 1989a, b: 10). The transaction cost approach is targeted, in the first place, at private goods. It covers property rights economics, transaction cost economics proper, and the more mathematical oriented agency (or contract) theory.9 The theory of collective action, is targeted at public goods of both a physical character, such as pollution or highways, and of an abstract character such as a ‘higher wage rate, a higher price, …, a regulation, a lower tax rate or a policy rule.’ (Nabli and Nugent 1989a, b: 14). The two general approaches are complementary. As long as transaction costs are not be prohibitively high, external effects of individual actions can be compensated by contractual arrangements between individual parties. Otherwise, collective action would obtain (Nabli and Nugent 1989a, b: 18). Contributors to this volume include the editors themselves and Samar K. Dutta, Timur Kuran, and Bruce H. Herrick.


1.4.2.4 Harriss, Hunter and Lewis

Harriss et al. (1995a, b) edited another conference issue on development economics10. According to them, the award of the Nobel Prize for Economics first to Ronald Coase in 1991 and then to Douglass North in 1993 is proof of the importance of the NIE. The NIE is able to explain non-market forms of organization as rational consequences of market failures. It thus, challenges the dominant role ascribed to the market by the orthodoxies of the last 10 years or so (Harriss et al. 1995a, b: 1). North, who participated at the conference, emphasized that the NIE retains the neoclassical assumptions of individual choice, subject to constraints. However, these constraints also include institutions. Transaction costs play an important role as well as ideas and ideologies. The latter are ‘a critical factor in the performance of economies, as the source of the diverse performance of economies, and the explanation for “inefficient” markets.’ (North 1995a: 19). Keynote speakers at this conference were Douglass C. North, Robert H. Bates and John Toye.


1.4.2.5 Drobak and Nye

Drobak and Nye (1997a, b) also edited a collection of papers that was presented at a celebration of the award of the 1993 Nobel Prize in Economics to Douglass North. The editors note that the NIE is less a distinct school ‘than a particular set of shared concerns grounded in existing economic theories and doctrines’ (Drobak and Nye (1997a, b): xv). New institutional economic historians, like North, begin with an appreciation of neoclassical price theory as a powerful tool for predicting many economic outcomes in the real world. But the neoclassical assumption of perfect individual rationality has to be watered down or even replaced by other assumptions about human behaviour.11 Central fields belonging to the NIE include transaction cost and property rights economics, political economy and public choice, quantitative economic history, cognition, ideology, and the role of path dependency. Speakers at this conference were, inter alia, Douglass C. North, Robert William Fogel, Avner Greif, Gary Libecap, Barry R. Weingast and Paul A. David.


1.4.2.6 Clague

Clague (1997) also edited a collection of papers on the application of the NIE to development issues. He describes the NIE as an expanded form of economics. It relaxes some of the strong assumptions of traditional economics with respect to the motivation of—and the information available to—individual decision makers and it widens the scope of economics to include political phenomena and the evolution of institutions. The NIE has called attention to the vital role of government administrative capacity in shaping the institutional environment of business. This might help to explain why bureaucracies perform well or badly and how the inefficient and corrupt ones can be reformed. Among the conference contributors were, inter alia, Mancur Olson, Philip Keefer, Elinor Ostrom, and Margaret Levi.


1.4.2.7 Summary

To sum up, all editors in our sample seem to agree that the NIE is not characterized or defined by a selection of fields but by the intellectual bond of its basic methodology. A clear majority favours contributions that belong to the ‘visible-hand’ approach to institutional economics. Only a small minority (one out of six in our sample) prefers components of its counterpart, the ‘invisible hand’ approach (Langlois). Those favouring the ‘visible hand’ approach agree that the foundation stones of the NIE are the same as those of neoclassical economics: methodological individualism and individual rational choice given a set of constraints. However, due to transaction or information costs, information is limited and, thus, institutions matter.

Like the old institutionalists,12 the new institutionalists start from a criticism of current economic theory for its “too high level of abstraction” (Williamson 1975: 1). But while the old institutionalists clearly refuse the abstract assumptions of classical or neoclassical economics, the new institutionalists tend to accept them, though, in a watered-down form due to transaction costs, Knightian uncertainty, bounded rationality and so forth, as well as from the perspective that institutional arrangements tend to substitute, to some extent, for these qualifications. In any case, all editors of our sample keep their distance from old institutional economics—most of them expressis verbis. 13 There are clearly major differences between the old and new institutional economics, however, as Rutherford (2001, 187) rightly points out, some aspects of the new institutionalism ‘do connect back to the old—including a tendency to spread beyond the standard neoclassical boundaries.’

Finally, all editors of the six collective volumes under consideration seem to agree that the composition of the fields of the NIE depends mainly on the particular object of research. In this respect, our sample is somewhat one-sided. Most of the six volumes are concerned with macroeconomic issues: three deal with issues of development economics, one with the new institutional economic approach to history and another with issues of evolutionary economics. Only one issue also includes micro economic problems. Obviously, this is not a representative mix of applications, in particular since a great deal of new institutional economic studies concern micro economic issues such as firms, industrial organization, antitrust, contractual relations, market organization and so forth. Still, our sample gives some insight into how the generic term ‘new institutional economics’ became a standard (or banner) under which a diverse group of economists assembled.


1.5 The Foundation of the International Society for New Institutional Economics


With the foundation of the International Society for New Institutional Economics (ISNIE), whose first conference was held at Washington University, St. Louis, Missouri, on 19–21 September 1997,14 the NIE came of age. The organizers advertised in the Internet the conference to scholars ‘working on transaction costs, contracting, political rules of the game, the rules of law, norms and culture, and who pursue these interests using standard scientific methods.’ (Furubotn and Richter 1997: 780).

At the inaugural conference, North, Williamson and Coase (in that order) basically described the NIE as has been described above. Although the immediate objective of the NIE is to replace the abstract, static models of neoclassical economics, Coase cautioned that a frontal attack on neoclassic models would be neither needed nor desirable. For appropriable theoretical development to be achieved, it is sufficient to focus on factual matters. Somewhat later Coase (1999: 1 ff.) noted that ISNIE would have a mission, namely ‘to replace the current analysis with something better, the new institutional economics…..The Influence of the new institutional economics will be exerted in the various sub-disciplines [of economics]. Guerrilla actions will take place, which will result in the new institutional economics dominating first one and than other of these sub-disciplines, as indeed is beginning to happen.’ But he added: ‘We will not replace price theory (supply and demand and all that) but will make it vastly more fruitful.’

A selection of the papers presented at the second annual conference of ISNIE at Paris in September 1998 has been published by Ménard (2000a, b), among these papers are contributions by the old guard—Ronald Coase, Douglass North, Oliver Williamson, Harold Demsetz, Yoram Barzel—but also by Masahiko Aoki who supports the ‘institution-as-equilibrium-of-a-game’ concept. Coase and North stress again that the representatives of the NIE don’t want to replace neoclassical theory but are trying to use these analytical tools ‘to study the working of the economic system’ (Coase 2000: 4 and 1999: 5 as quoted above). But that appears to contradict North’s concept of the ‘cognitive science/institutional approach to history’ or Williamson’s casuistic technique to broach bounded rationality. Why not admit that a change in paradigm is already under way?


1.6 Summary and Comments


Williamson (1975: 1) introduced the NIE as a generic term for a divers group of already existing modern economic studies of institutions. The term was later mentioned here and there, but it took 8 years until conference organizers first used it. After 10 or 15 years it became a standard under which economists who are interested in aspects of the economics of institutions assembled. As it turns out, the term NIE is now generally used as a name of what we call the ‘visible-hand’ approach to institutional economics.

Table 1.1 shows the nine modern institutional economic fields, which have been described as part of the NIE in the above-mentioned literature. These fields were developed by different scholars during the 1960s and early 1970s. Core fields of the NIE are:



  • transaction cost economics (Coase, Williamson),


  • property rights economics (Coase, Alchian),


  • economic contract theory (formally: Spence, Mirrlees, Stiglitz, informally: Williamson, Macneil), and


  • the new institutional approach to history (North).

There are reasons to follow Nabli and Nugent (1989a, b) and to include the theory of collective action (Olson 1965) in the NIE. While property rights economics and the formal parts of contract theory still assume perfect rationality, this is not the case with transaction cost economics and the new institutional approach to history of North.

Williamson (1975: 4) assumes men to be only boundedly rational, North (1995a, b: 18 f.) writes that a theory of institutions has to begin with a ‘modification of the instrumental rationality assumption’ and Coase (1984: 231) regards the assumption ‘that man is a rational utility maximizer’ to be both ‘unnecessary and misleading.’ The assumption of perfect rationality is thus being abandoned by leading neo-institutionalists.

Two branches of the NIE developed after Coase (1937, 1960): the transaction cost economics (TCE) of Williamson (1985a, b) and the new institutional economics of history (NIEH) in the sense of Douglass North (1986). Next to Coase, Williamson and North became the two leading representatives of the NIE. The difference between the ‘Williamsonian’ and the ‘Northian’ approach is described as follows by Ensminger (1992: 21 f.).

While Williamson (1981) ‘takes the position that institutions are expressly designed to reduce transaction costs and that, in competitive markets, those that fail to do so will not survive.’ On the other hand, North (1981: Chap. 3, 1990: 8, 52) argues vehemently against the view ‘that institutions are created only to reduce transaction costs and increase economic efficiency.’ The reasons for inefficient institutions are inefficiencies of political markets, ‘democracy in polity is not to be equated with competitive markets in the economy.’ (North 1990: 51).15

However, both approaches hardly square with the constantly referred to neoclassical economics and seem unwilling to make the break to a fundamentally new paradigm.16 While this is not achieved, one should at least be ready to apply different, problem related analytical methods for different objects of economic research and define the science of economics by its objects, instead of its method, as is done in other applied sciences. Economics is more appropriately compared to engineering or medicine than to physics or biology (see Varian 1993: 2 f.).

The Williamsonian approach to the NIE is mainly applied in microeconomic fields like the theory of firm, of industrial organization, antitrust and the economics of organization. The Northian approach is used to tackle macroeconomic issues such as the history of national economies, of development economics and transformation economics.


2 Meaning of the NIE


In this section, I will restrict myself to the meaning of the Williamsonian and the Northian approach to the NIE and proceed as follows. First, I will provide a brief description of the analytical core of Williamson’s TCE and North’s NIEH. Then I will compare the two approaches with each other. Finally, I will briefly discuss what some of their critics have said.


2.1 The Analytical Core of Williamson’s Transaction Cost Economics17


Oliver Williamson points out, inter alia, that non-standard contracts may—but need not—result from monopolistic practices. The reason is that transaction specific-investments can play an essential role after the conclusion of a contract. Williamson illustrates this by using the concept of fundamental transformation. After contract conclusion, the parties find themselves locked into a bilateral monopoly situation, whereas before they were free to choose with whom to trade. Transaction-specific investments of whatever kind (if only in the form of time invested in search, inspection, and bargaining) are the reason for this transformation. In addition, Williamson takes into account the fact that we do not know what the future will bring. Thus, adaptability to the unforeseen becomes an issue. Under Knightian uncertainty it is impossible to write a complete contract that details all possible future contingencies.18 Therefore, contracts are unavoidably incomplete. They contain loopholes and the lock-in of the parties may invite opportunistic behaviour by the other side because the parties may be unable to verify their case to a third party (e.g., a court) due to information costs (a special kind of transaction costs). Court ordering may thus have to be supplemented or even substituted by private ordering to protect the parties effectively against opportunism of their trade partners. There are various ways to organize the governance structure of a contractual relationship. Their efficacy depends on the particular circumstance, including the size of specific investments and the frequency of transactions between the parties. To sum up, one may say that transaction cost economics (or “the economics of governance” as Williamson 2005 also calls it) joins three fundamental concepts: adaptability, governance, and transaction costs.19 TCE has been supported by numerous empirical studies (for an overview, see Shelanski and Klein 1995 or Boerner and Macher 2002 20).

Williamson’s TCE (or economics of governance) is a theory of contracts under conditions of uncertainty and asymmetric information, in which un-programmed adaptations matter.21 Legal enforcement and self-enforcement complement each other with the aim ‘to design workable order-preserving mechanisms for adapting to disturbances.’22 Both court ordering and private ordering characterize the governance structure (or ‘organization’) of non-standard contractual relationships. Attentive actors agree before they come to terms on a governance structure that they regard suitable. Market and hierarchy are two of the imaginable ideal types of possible governance structures. It is important to see that the choice of an efficient (or better: efficacious) governance structure results not from optimizing some target function subject to a set of constraints. It may rather be understood as a form of boundedly rational or ‘suitable’ choice from a set of governance structures in the sense of Selten’s hypothesis of the casuistic structure of boundedly rational strategies (see Furubotn and Richter 2005: 180).23 Which governance structure the parties choose depends on the particular situation. The problem for the parties is then to agree about both the ‘right’ diagnosis (of the situation) and the ‘best’ cure (the governance structure). Williamson’s (1985a, b: 79) table of ‘efficient governance’ may be understood as an example of how to think, not as an answer to the parties’ decision problem. The idea is, to think less like a physicist and more like a physician.


2.2 The Analytical Core of North’s New Institutional Economics of History


Douglass North aims at an economic explanation of the structure and performance of economies through time.24 He starts from the simple observation that human cooperation requires rules of behaviour, namely institutional constraints, which in the final analysis define the opportunity set of individuals.25 Because of transaction costs, the nature of the institutional framework plays a major role in the performance of an economy.26 It reduces the uncertainty of human interaction and, thus, the costs of cooperation.27 Persistent changes in relative prices, due to lasting exogenous changes (such as changes in total population, knowledge or ideology28 or to competition among organizations29) will lead actors to realize that they could be better off under alternative institutional arrangements and result in institutional change. In general, institutional change will be incremental and path dependent—incremental because large changes will create too many opponents, and path dependent30 because institutional change is governed by the kind of knowledge and skills that actors have invested in.31 Due to high (sunk or variable) transaction costs, inefficient institutions may persist for long periods of time.32

Institutional constraints comprise informal and formal rules of behaviour.33 Informal rules comprise norms, conventions, and internally held codes of conduct (North 2005, 50). Formal rules consist of political rules (example: the constitution34), economic rules (examples: property rights,35 contract laws) and contractual agreements between actors (example: sales contract). Political rules lead to economic rules, ‘though the causality runs both ways.’36 The enforcement of rules matters. Self-enforcement would be ideal but is frequently not promising.37 In general, legal enforcement is more effective.38 However, the coercive force given to the State may be used by those in power to their own advantage.39 In a simple model, North (1981, 28) interprets the State as a ruler who maximizes his profit subject to two basic constraints: the degree of political competition with rivals and with other States, and transaction costs. For both reasons, the property-rights structure, which maximizes the social product, may not maximize the ruler’s (long-term) monopoly rents. North’s judgment is rather pessimistic. He argues that, in order to stabilize his power, the ruler will agree to a property rights structure that is favourable to those groups with close access to alternative rulers, regardless of its effects upon efficiency. And because of the costs of determining and collecting taxes, a less efficient property-rights structure may be more favourable to the revenue-maximizing ruler.40

North’s concept of the NIEH aims at a general theory of the interaction between polity and economy. It is, to this extent, an application of the economic theory of politics to economic history. However, in contrast to public choice theory and the theory of collective action,41 North assumes imperfect individual rationality and emphasizes the role of ideology. He rejects ‘rational choice and efficient market hypotheses’.42 Instead, he opines that because of imperfect individual rationality

mental models, institutions and ideologies all contribute to the process by which human beings interpret and order environment. Mental models are, to some degree, unique to each individual. Ideologies and institutions are created and provide more closely shared perceptions and ordering of the environment. (Denzau and North 1994: 21)


2.3 Comparing the Williamsonian and Northian Approaches to the NIE


Both approaches deal with the same object: the institution. Williamson (1985a, b) prefers to speak of ‘governance structure,’ North (1981, 1990) uses terms like ‘rules of behaviour’, ‘institutional constraints’ or ‘structure.’ In addition, North (1990) distinguishes between ‘institutional arrangements’ and ‘institutional environment,’ the former being a subset of the latter, which are a set of fundamental political, social, and legal ground rules that govern economic and political activity (Davis and North 1971: 133). North stresses the role of ideology. Thus, we may note as follows (in a strongly simplified manner):



  • TCE analyses the ‘institutions of governance’ given the institutional environment. Its objects of research are agreed on arrangements essentially between two actors.43 Such institutions deal essentially with the transfer or administration of private goods and may themselves be considered to be private goods. They are the result of individual action.


  • The NIEH analyses the ‘institutional environment’ including ideology. Its objects of research are the informal and formal institutional constraints that control the behaviour of more than two actors. An institution in this sense deals with the provision or administration of public goods; in fact, it is itself a public good.44 It is the result of explicit or implicit collective actions.

TCE abstracts from the interaction between economic and political decision-making. It takes norms, customs, mores, tradition and so forth as givens, the latter with the argument that ‘institutions at this level change very slowly—in the order of centuries or millennia’ (Williamson 2000

Only gold members can continue reading. Log In or Register to continue