Introduction to the Regulation of Electricity Markets




(1)
Dept. of Accounting and Commercial Law, Hanken School of Economics, Vaasa, Finland

 




3.1 General Remarks


This chapter gives an introduction to some fundamental aspects of the regulation of electricity markets in EU law.

The regulatory regime for electricity markets consists of many components: the regulation of electricity markets; the regulation of financial markets; the regulation of energy efficiency and greenhouse gas emissions; and competition law. Electricity markets are “affected with the public interest”1 in various ways and different components of the regulatory regime are designed to further different policy objectives.

The regulation of electricity markets is regarded as important for many reasons. (a) The first is simply that energy issues have attracted plenty of political interest. Energy issues have become a large battlefield for politicians with conflicting preferences. (b) The second is the size and growth of the electricity market. While the energy industry is a large and important sector of the European economy, the production and consumption of electricity grow faster than the overall energy market. To illustrate, the attainment of the EU’s 2020 climate-change target requires more electricity, more transmission capacity, and smarter grids.2 The 2030 targets require more effort. (c) The third is security of supply. An effective EU-wide electricity market could increase the security of energy supply and help to reduce the EU’s reliance on imported gas. (d) Fourth, the regulation of the electricity market could help to sustain the competitiveness of European industry. While a lower price of electricity contributes to higher economic growth, higher tariffs hamper growth. (e) Fifth, it would not be possible to develop an effectively functioning emissions trading mechanism without a competitive electricity market.

We begin with an overview of liberalisation (Sect. 3.2), the several regulatory sectors (Sect. 3.3), and a brief history of electricity regulation (Sect. 3.4). There is an introduction to the most important electricity directives and network codes (Sect. 3.5). In addition, it is necessary to discuss competition law (Sect. 3.6), environmental regulation (Sect. 3.7), as well as the regulation of marketplaces and financial markets (Sect. 3.8) to the extent that they can be relevant for electricity producers.


3.2 Liberalisation


Liberalising the internal electricity market would be a big task, because it is not possible to liberalise European electricity markets without extensive regulation.

There are examples of how things can go wrong. In California, the goal was a competitive market for the buying and selling of power. While markets were deregulated at the wholesale level, price caps were used at the retail level. This led to the Western Energy Crisis (the Californian electricity crisis).3 The German electricity market shows how the preferential treatment of electricity generated from renewable sources (RES-E) can increase greenhouse gas emissions, increase retail electricity prices, limit investment, and reduce security of supply.

There are also better examples of liberalisation. The more mature liberalised European markets can be found in the Nordic countries for electricity and in Britain for electricity and gas. There is a new, north-west and central European power-trading zone with Germany in the middle (the NWE region).4

Obviously, electricity producers would benefit from a fully liberalised internal electricity market. It would help electricity firms to scale up5 and even to increase the number of market participants. Unbundling that restricts some forms of vertical integration is bound to increase other forms of vertical integration by facilitating access to end consumers and to give incentives for horizontal integration.6

However, year 2014 did not bring about a fully liberalised internal electricity market. The new legislation was not intended to liberalise markets—at least not from the perspective of electricity producers. The regulatory regime facilitating the internal electricity market has other objectives. What explains the low level of liberalisation?


Objectives of Regulation

To begin with, the “liberalisation” of electricity markets does not mean deregulation.7 The efficiency of electricity markets can only be facilitated by extensive regulation. In the EU, energy markets are governed by a regulatory regime that is both detailed and large in scope.

The regulatory regime is partly necessary because of the nature of electricity markets. For instance, the functioning of physical electricity markets requires detailed standardisation for technical reasons.

There are reasons that increase the scope of the EU regulatory regime and its level of detail. First, the regulatory regime is designed to further many different and sometimes conflicting public policy objectives. For instance, one of the present-day goals of the EU is to foster energy efficiency and energy saving, but this is not the only objective of EU energy policy. It should also: ensure security of energy supply; ensure the functioning of the energy market; foster the interconnection of energy networks; and foster the development of new and renewable forms of energy.8 Second, in some policy areas (such as financial markets and competition), the objectives of the EU have resulted in extensive harmonisation of Member States’ national regulatory regimes.

It would be just as misleading to talk about deregulation in the US. FERC’s regulation of RTO/ISOs has been described as “pervasive”.

Unlike the SEC and the CFTC, FERC is a “rate regulator” with a mandate grounded in the Federal Power Act of 1935. It has an obligation to ensure that prices in wholesale electricity markets, and the terms and conditions of the various products and services used to establish prices in these markets, are “just and reasonable”. RTOs and ISOs cannot establish unilaterally their rules of operation. Instead, RTOs/ISOs are subject to a FERC-administered program comprehensively regulating their planning of the transmission grid, their dispatch of generation operation of the grid, their compliance with reliability standards, and their administration of the markets they operate. Every material action taken by an RTO/ISO in performing these functions must be authorised by a rule. Every rule must be embodied in a tariff. Every tariff provision must be filed with and adjudicated by the FERC to meet the requirements of the Federal Power Act.9

The collapse of Enron increased the regulation of financial electricity markets first in the US.10 It has increased the regulation of financial markets in the EU as well.


Market-Based Mechanisms

Rather than deregulation, the liberalisation of electricity markets means the adoption of new legislation designed to: increase access to the market (open up the market); facilitate increased use of market-based mechanisms; and facilitate the coupling of markets.

The use of market-based mechanisms means: (a) the introduction of electricity exchanges for the trading of spot electricity, electricity forwards, and electricity derivatives in a similar manner as securities and commodities are traded in the financial market; (b) the introduction of auctions for balance energy; (c) the introduction of auctions for the allocation of transmission capacity; and (d) a secondary market for transmission capacity.


Not the Same Thing as Creating a Single Market

Liberalisation is not the same thing as creating a single (or internal) market for electricity (whether liberalised or not). An internal market relates to the absence of barriers to cross-border trade.

Creating the internal market for electricity is not uncomplicated, because the markets traditionally have been national. The integration of electricity markets requires breaking up vertically integrated utilities, investments in new interconnectors between national grids, effective cooperation between transmission system operators, and a clear and stable regulatory framework to foster investment in generation and transmission capacity.

Creating the internal electricity market requires large investments in electricity infrastructure, and it can only be created in stages. The first stage was creating electricity markets that were regional rather than national. The Commission planned seven regional markets for electricity. The second stage is to integrate the regional markets.11


No Liberalisation of the Wholesale Market for Electricity Producers

In any case, there are ways to liberalise wholesale markets for electricity producers and ways to liberalise retail markets for end consumers. They are not the same thing.

As regards wholesale markets, it would not be enough to liberalise just one market or national electricity markets. There are many wholesale electricity markets in the EU and the markets are connected in various ways.12

The EU seems to have focused on liberalising retail markets from a consumer perspective rather than physical wholesale markets from a producer perspective. (a) The regulation of physical wholesale markets at the EU level is largely based on central planning with several contradictory objectives. The objectives include the operational efficiency of the electricity system, fostering the use of particular generation technologies that are not efficient (RES-E), fostering investment in RES-E even in the most isolated Member States and regions, ensuring that consumers can purchase energy at affordable prices, ensuring nevertheless that competition is free, ensuring security of supply, and increasing the liquidity and transparency of electricity wholesale markets.13 (b) In the physical wholesale market, the EU seems to have focused on aspects related to financial markets (such as clearing) and the trading of standardised contracts (in particular on exchanges) rather than the supply of electricity as such (under bilateral or other physical contracts).14

Wholesale markets are not truly liberalised when the Member States are asked to discriminate against electricity producers depending on their production technology and when the Member States do not have faith in the market mechanism.15

The prevailing competition model in the EU is limited supplier competition (see Sect. 2.​6.​3). The low level of liberalisation and the preferential treatment of RES-E have: increased investment in RES-E installations; led to overcapacities in generation; reduced wholesale prices and increased retail prices; reduced investment in new generation installations other than RES-E generation installations; made old coal-burning installations more competitive; contributed little to a reduction of greenhouse gas emissions; and made the business of electricity producers more difficult.16 The low level of liberalisation and the preferential treatment of RES-E also mean higher exposure to legal and regulatory risk as well as problems caused by the lower level of liquidity.17


3.3 Regulatory Sectors


The regulatory regime for electricity markets serves various potentially conflicting policy objectives, because EU law has conflicting objectives and the regulatory regime is based both on the four freedoms and sectoral legislation in many overlapping areas (competition law, financial regulation, environmental law, and energy law).


Competition Law

The EC Treaty that preceded the TFEU made it clear that it was not enough to apply the four freedoms in the internal market. It was just as important to ensure that competition is free.18 The TFEU requires the EU and the Member States to conduct their economic policies in accordance with the principle of an open market economy with free competition.19 Since Almelo, it has been clear that EU competition law applies to the electricity sector.20

EU competition law has played an important role in the regulation of the electricity markets even for three other general reasons. On one hand, there is no single European energy regulator to control the markets and Member States may be slow to open their markets as this could be to the detriment of their own national champions or state-owned utilities. On the other, there is a well-developed body of competition law in the EU because market behaviour is constrained by EU competition law (Articles 101, 102, and 107 TFEU), national competition laws (such as the GWB and UWG21), or both.22 Moreover, the Commission has both wide powers to enforce competition law and an opportunity to do so in the light of the existence of monopolies and the use of long-term contracts in electricity markets.23


Financial Regulation

The regulation of energy markets resembles financial regulation in many respects and is partly governed by the same regulatory framework. After the restructuring and unbundling of electricity markets and the growth of physical and financial electricity exchanges as well as OTC-trading, the regulatory regime for financial markets has replaced competition law as the most important regulatory regime complementing the sectoral regulation of energy. Much of this book focuses on the financial regulation of electricity markets.

The most important EU legislation in this area consists of MiFID II/MiFIR,24 EMIR,25 MAR/MAD II,26 REMIT,27 CRD IV/CRR,28 as well as the Financial Collateral Directive29 and the Settlement Finality Directive.30 Electricity markets are influenced even by other sectoral directives such as insurance directives31 and the UCITS Directive that regulate the use of derivative contracts for some potential market participants.32


Environmental Law

The 20/20/20 targets adopted by the European Council in March 2007 have had a major impact on the electricity industry. Their impact is not limited to the introduction of greenhouse emission permits for installations33 and a market-based mechanism for emissions trading under Directive 2003/87/EC (as amended).34 In practice, the environmental law regime makes investment in electricity generation and transmission installations largely regulation-driven and subject to regulatory permits (Sect. 3.7.7). As the market mechanism is replaced by central planning, the costs of meeting the 20/20/20 targets are likely to be much higher than they could be.

The 20/20/20 targets are part of the Europe 2020 strategy.35 Of the three targets, a 20 % reduction in greenhouse gas emissions when compared to 1990 levels and raising the share of energy consumption produced from renewable resources to 20 % are nationally binding targets implemented by The climate and energy package.36 The third of the targets is a 20 % improvement in the EU’s energy-efficiency compared to 1990 levels.

The Europe 2020 strategy is complemented by the 2030 Framework proposed by the Commission in January 201437 and agreed on by the European Council in October 2014. The main objectives set out in the 2030 Framework are: a reduction in greenhouse gas emissions by 40 % relative to the 1990 level; an EU-wide binding target for renewable energy of at least 27 %; renewed ambitions for energy efficiency policies; and a new governance system and a set of new indicators to ensure a competitive and secure energy system.


Particular Treaty Provisions on Energy Markets

The regulation of electricity markets is based on the provisions of the Treaty on European Union (TEU) and the TFEU. The Treaties contain particular provisions on energy markets. Some of these provisions regulate the division of competence between the bodies of the EU and the Member States. Others regulate how and for what purpose these competences may be exercised.

The competences may be exercised for certain purposes. To begin with, the TEU defines the general objectives of the EU. In addition to establishing an internal market and various other objectives, the EU shall “work for the sustainable development of Europe based on balanced economic growth and price stability, a highly competitive social market economy, aiming at full employment and social progress, and a high level of protection and improvement of the quality of the environment” as well as “promote scientific and technological advance”.38

The TFEU lays down two broad objectives for the EU’s energy policy in an effort to clarify the relative weight of the various general objectives of the EU set out in the TEU. The two broad objectives include, first, the establishment and functioning of the internal market and, second, the preservation and improvement of the environment.

To attain these broad objectives, the EU’s energy policy has more specific goals. It aims to: (a) ensure the functioning of the EU’s energy market; (b) ensure security of energy supply in the EU; (c) promote energy efficiency and energy saving and the development of new and renewable forms of energy; and (d) promote the interconnection of energy networks.39 According to the TFEU, the setting-up of an area without internal frontiers requires even trans-European energy infrastructures.40 The EU’s energy policy is also influenced by its environmental policy and legislation. The fact that environmental policy can influence energy sources and the structure of a Member State’s energy supply has been considered in the decision-making process.41


3.4 Brief History of Electricity Regulation


The regulation of energy markets has long roots in the EU.42 In fact, the origins of the EU lie in the regulation of the energy industry.


Treaties

The European Coal and Steel Community, which was established by the Treaty of Paris in 1951, created a common market for coal and steel between France, Germany, Italy, Belgium, Luxembourg, and the Netherlands. The ECSC Treaty was in force from 23 July 1952 to 23 July 2002. The European Atomic Energy Community was established by the 1957 Euratom Treaty, one of the two Treaties of Rome.

Energy is nowadays mentioned in the Treaty on the Functioning of the EU (TFEU). In addition, energy markets fall within the scope of the four freedoms and EU competition law.


Liberalisation

The process of liberalising the European electricity market started in the 1990s when the Community decided to open up gas and electricity markets to competition and to create an integrated European energy market. The Community’s energy markets policy has been implemented through sector-specific legislation and by means of EU competition law.43

In the US, the Public Utility regulatory Policy Act of 1978 (PURPA) is regarded as the first step towards creating more competitive power markets. Section 210 of PURPA encouraged non-utility generators to build power plants using principally non-fossil energy sources. PURPA was followed by the Energy Policy Act of 1992 (EPA). According to EPA, an “exempt wholesale generator” could own a generation facility and sell power exclusively into the wholesale power market. In 1996, the FERC issued Order No. 888 designed to unbundle all the services offered by existing public utilities into their various components so that the new participants would also have access to those services and a chance to compete against such utilities on a level playing field. By Order No. 2000, the FERC directed that “all transmission owning entities in the Nation, including non-public utility entities, place their transmission facilities under the control of appropriate regional transmission institutions (RTOs)”.44

FERC is a federal agency created in 1977 to regulate, among other things, interstate wholesale sales and transportation of gas and electricity at “just and reasonable” rates.45


Directives, Three Legislative Packages

The EU electricity markets have been restructured gradually on a piece-meal basis. The first step was to adopt two directives in 1990 to improve price transparency and the use of the grid for electricity transit.

According to the Price Transparency Directive, undertakings that supply gas or electricity to industrial end-users must disclose the prices and terms and the price systems in use.46 The Electricity Transit Directive facilitated transit of electricity between high-voltage grids. The Member States were given a duty to take the necessary measures.47 Transit contracts were to be negotiated between the entities responsible for the grids concerned rather than between a supplier/consumer and the operator of each grid.48 The Electricity Transit Directive also laid down the general standards for the conditions of transit such as non-discrimination, fairness, and no endangering of security of supply and quality of service.49

The EU’s ambitious restructuring and integration process started a few years later when the first of three legislative packages was adopted.50 The first legislative package consisted of the First Electricity Directive51 (Sect. 3.5.1) and a similar Directive for the natural gas market in 1996. According to the First Electricity Directive, the internal market in electricity needs to be established gradually.52

The process was reinforced by the second legislative package and the Second Electricity Directive (Sect. 3.5.2)53 in 2003 as well as the third legislative package and the Third Electricity Directive (Sect. 3.5.4)54 in 2009.

The Third Electricity Directive is the directive that requires the effective unbundling of generation and network assets. In addition, conditions for access to the network for cross-border exchanges in electricity were introduced by Regulation 714/2009 to encourage cross-border competition.55

The European Council set the target of 2014 for the completion of a fully liberalised internal electricity market. Its cornerstone is the Third Electricity Directive.56 ACER (Agency for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators)57 and ENTSO-E (European Network of Transmission System Operators for Electricity) were created to improve the legislatory process.


Target Model

In addition to the general 2014 target, there is also a target model. In 2008, a Project Coordination Group of experts was given the task of developing an EU-wide target model for the integration of regional electricity markets. According to this target model, a single price-coupling mechanism (implicit auction) should be implemented across all European countries (Sect. 5.​2).58 Regulation 714/2009 is in line with this target model.59

The electricity market target model is a developing set of proposals. It is based on two broad principles: “energy only” regional markets (electricity producers’ revenues should primarily depend on the price for each marginal unit of energy supplied); and market coupling.60 The target model is set out in the Framework Guidelines on Capacity Allocation and Congestion Management for Electricity published by ACER in July 2011 (Sect. 5.​1).61


Deeper Harmonisation

The 2014 target for the completion of the internal electricity market does not prevent the Member States from taking action to increase market integration.

The Nordic regulators (NordREG) have taken steps to create, by 2015, a common harmonised market with a supplier-centric model as its cornerstone. The long-term vision is a fully integrated market.

NordREG has defined these goals as follows62: (a) A common harmonised market means “a market where the most critical barriers for suppliers to establishing business in another Nordic country are eliminated. In the common harmonised market legislation regarding key issues such as responsibilities in the customer interface, billing, risk management, tax collection, number of contracts, making and ending contracts, universal service (supplier of last resort and default supplier), supplier switching, moving, information exchange, data format, regulation regarding DSO neutrality, balance settlement, access to data and metering, may or will be subject to changes”. (b) A supplier centric model “is characterised by the defined customer interface, where a majority of the customer contacts will be handled by the supplier. However, the DSO will still have ultimate responsibility towards customers regarding strictly network related issues”.63 (c) A fully integrated market “is the long term vision of a market where all relevant legislation and processes are harmonised to the extent that they are almost identical”. However, this does not include the harmonisation of business legislation of general application such as tax laws.


3.5 The Electricity Directives



3.5.1 The First Electricity Directive: Construction of Generation Capacity


The present market structure is the result of the adoption of three energy packages. We can study the three electricity directives in more detail to the extent that they are relevant for electricity producers. The restructuring of the European electricity markets started with the First Electricity Directive.


Construction of New Generation Capacity

The First Directive made it easier to construct new generation capacity. For this purpose, Member States could choose an authorisation procedure and/or a tendering procedure. Both must be conducted in accordance with objective, transparent and non-discriminatory criteria.64 The Directive listed the permitted criteria.65


Unbundling

The First Directive did not prohibit complete vertical integration. Integrated electricity firms could still own transmission or distribution assets. However, the First Directive required the separation of functions. Member States were required to designate operators for the transmission and distribution systems.66 The TSO had to be “independent at least in management terms from other activities not relating to the transmission system”.67


Retail Competition

The First Directive made an attempt to increase retail competition by giving eligible customers—distribution companies and large consumers—a right to choose the supplier.68


Access to the Network

Moreover, TSOs and DSOs were required to grant non-discriminatory access to the network under negotiated third party access (nTPA), regulated third party access (rTPA), or the “single buyer” option. (a) Germany was the only Member State to opt for negotiated third-party access (nTPA).69 Under negotiated access, generators and retail suppliers were required to negotiate with the system operators for access to the network. An indicative range of prices had to be published. (b) All other Member States opted for regulated third-party access (rTPA). Under regulated access, generators and retail suppliers were allowed access at published tariffs. (c) Under the single buyer option, a Member State could designate a “single buyer” responsible for purchasing the country’s (or a smaller region’s) electricity needs. The single buyer would determine which plants were used.70


Effect

The First Electricity Directive did not go very far. First, it did not require a wholesale market to be set up. Even if companies were free to build new power plants, they did not necessarily have the means to bring their power to market.71 Second, the unbundling requirements did not guarantee independence of access to the network. Third, retail competition was restricted, with no more than a few thousand consumers able to choose by 2003 even in the largest countries. Fourth, it did not require an independent sector regulator.72


3.5.2 The Second Electricity Directive: Retail Competition


In practice, most countries went much further than was required to meet the terms of the First Directive.73 This encouraged the Commission to introduce new proposals to close loopholes. The First Electricity Directive was replaced by the Second Electricity Directive designed to cure some of its shortcomings.74

The Second Electricity Directive placed more stringent requirements on Member States to de-integrate their electricity industries and introduce competition in power generation and the retail market. The Second Directive placed requirements in the same four areas covered by the First Directive but went further. Moreover, it required the designation of an independent sector regulator.


Construction of New Generating Capacity

The rules on the construction of new capacity built on the provisions of the First Directive. But while the First Directive permitted the Member States to choose an authorisation procedure and/or a tendering procedure for the construction of new capacity,75 the Second Directive made the authorisation procedure the main rule.76 Tendering may only be used if the authorisation procedure fails to produce sufficient capacity to ensure supply security.77 The authorisation procedure was the method preferred by the Member States.78


Retail Competition

The Second Directive went much further than the First Directive in fostering retail competition. The Second Directive opened up the market first for all non-household customers and then for all customers. Since July 2007, all customers have been allowed to choose their retail electricity supplier.79


Unbundling

The Second Directive did not prohibit complete vertical integration. Like the First Directive, the Second Directive distinguished between ownership and operation of a TSO or DSO that is part of a vertically integrated undertaking.

Unbundling requirements relating to the firm’s operation were complemented by requirements relating to the firm’s legal structure. In other words, the TSO or DSO must be independent not only functionally but even organisationally. The TSO or DSO must comply with forms of independence: independence in terms of legal form, independence of organisation, and independence of decision-making from other activities not relating to transmission distribution.80

However, there were no unbundling requirements relating to corporate ownership. The TSOs or DSOs could be under the same corporate ownership as a company active in generation and/or retail provided that they were legally distinct companies.81


Network Access

The Second Directive simplified third party access (TPA). The negotiated access and the “single buyer” option were withdrawn. The regulated TPA became mandatory.82


Regulatory Authorities

While the First Directive did not address the question of effective monitoring, the Second Directive required the designation of independent regulatory authorities. They were to be responsible for “ensuring non-discrimination, effective competition and the efficient functioning of the market”.83


Effect

The Second Electricity Directive did not yet create an internal market in electricity. It did not create a “fully open market” that would have enabled “all consumers freely to choose their suppliers and all suppliers freely to deliver to their customers”.84 Neither did it open the electricity sector fully to competition. First, there was no specific requirement to introduce a wholesale electricity market. Second, the company operating the network could still be owned by a company active in a generation or retail business.85 Third, there were no specific measures to break up dominant companies (“national champions”). Fourth, the Second Directive did not regulate the question of security of supply in detail. Monitoring was increased for this purpose.86


3.5.3 The Directive on Security of Supply


After the Commission’s 2000 green paper on supply security87 and the 2003 power blackouts in Europe and the USA, voices were raised for more regulation. This led to the adoption of the Directive on security of supply88 that required greater government involvement.

The purpose of the Directive was to ensure: an adequate level of generation capacity; an adequate balance between supply and demand; and an appropriate level of interconnection between Member States for the development of the internal market.89

The nature of the duties laid down by the Directive is fairly general.90 Member States must: ensure a high level of security of supply 91; establish a regulatory framework that fosters network investment 92; take appropriate measures to maintain a balance between supply and demand93; and ensure that transmission system operators set the minimum operational rules and obligations on network security.94 The Directive on security of supply paved the way for the third legislative package.


3.5.4 The Third Electricity Directive: Effective Unbundling



Core Rules


The third legislative package was adopted by the Commission in 2009. The Third Electricity Directive95 was designed to cure the failings of the Second Electricity Directive.96 The Third Directive introduced more effective unbundling rules97 designed to break up dominant companies,98 gave large non-household customers the right to choose several suppliers,99 and fostered energy production from renewable sources.100 Moreover, the third legislative package created a European Network of Transmission System Operators (ENTSO) for electricity (ENTSO-E) and gas,101 and an Agency for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators (ACER).102


Construction of New Generating Capacity

The Third Electricity Directive gave new incentives to invest in new power generation capacity. There were two main changes.

While the Second Directive recognised “the nature of the primary sources” as part of the permitted criteria for the grant of authorisations for the construction of generating capacity,103 the third Directive went much further in fostering investment in energy from renewable sources and the reduction of emissions.104 In addition, the Third Directive was designed to foster investment in decentralised electricity generation.105


Retail and Wholesale Competition

The Second Directive gave all customers the right to choose their suppliers. The Third Directive increased competition in both the retail and the wholesale market by giving large non-household customers a right to enter into contracts with several suppliers to secure their electricity requirements. Such customers were thus protected against exclusivity clauses.106


Network Access, TPA Rights

One of the main goals of the Third Electricity Directive was to achieve non-discriminatory network access.107 Non-discriminatory grid access at the transmission level determines downstream access to customers at the retail level.108 Competition can be increased further by cross-border grid access for new suppliers of electricity.109

Creating the internal electricity market would not have been possible without particular third-party access rights (TPA rights) for electricity firms.110 The European Commission based the legislative reforms that lead to TPA rights on three foundations. The first was that the technique of an imposed competition based on obligatory access was already part of EU competition law.111 The second was that the energy sector was subject to an extensive regulatory framework in the Member States.112 Competition law would not have been enough to open markets.113 The third was the prevailing view that the provision of energy is a public service.114

This is reflected in the Third Electricity Directive. According to the Directive, the Member States may impose on undertakings operating in the electricity sector, in the general economic interest, public service obligations.115 There must also be a system of third party access to the transmission and distribution systems. It must be based on published tariffs, applicable to all eligible customers, and applied objectively and without discrimination between system users.116 The transmission or distribution system operator may not refuse access unless it lacks the necessary capacity.117 The Member States may also take measures to ensure a level playing field.118 Such measures must be proportionate, non-discriminatory and transparent.119

On the other hand, there are limitations to third party access rights.

First, the corresponding duties to grant third party access apply to transmission or distribution system operators. They do not apply to electricity firms that cannot be regarded as TSOs or DSOs. In citiworks, the CJEU noted that voltage is the sole distinguishing criterion between transmission and distribution.120 Particular transmission or distribution systems were not excluded from the scope of the Second Electricity Directive by reason of their size or consumption of electricity. There were particular rules for “small isolated systems” and “micro isolated systems”.121

Second, third party access rights do not include the right to be connected to the grid. In Sabatauskas,122 the question was whether a party is free to choose the system (a transmission system or a distribution system) to which it wishes to connect and whether the system operator must permit connection to the system.123 According to the CJEU, the terms “access” and “connection” mean different things. The term “access” is linked to the supply of electricity. The term “connection” is used in a technical context and relates to physical connection to the system. Therefore, third party access rights under the Second Electricity Directive did not include connection to the system.124

Third, refusal to permit a grid connection or access to the grid does not always amount to abuse of a dominant position (Article 102 TFEU, see Sect. 3.7).


Effective Unbundling

While the Second Electricity Directive required legal and functional/operational unbundling but not ownership unbundling, the Third Directive requires “effective unbundling”. Effective unbundling means the “effective separation of networks from activities of generation and supply”.125

US wholesale markets and interstate transmission are regulated by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC). In 1996, the FERC ordered utilities to unbundle their generation, transmission, and distribution functions and provide non-discriminatory access to the national electricity grid (FERC Order 888).126


Security of Supply

According to the Third Electricity Directive, security of supply is fostered in three main ways. (a) The first is the independence of system operators facilitated by unbundling.127 (b) The second is investment in electricity generation. Investments are made easier by unbundling and pricing signals.128 (c) The third is the development of interconnections.

There can be no internal market for electricity without cross-border interconnections. Without cross-border interconnections, it would be difficult to reach the Directive’s objectives relating to security of supply and competitive prices.129 For this reason, the Third Electricity Directive requires the Member States to provide adequate economic incentives for the maintenance and construction of interconnection capacity and to enable an adequate level of interconnection capacity even in other ways.130


Regulatory Authority


The Third Electricity Directive provides that each Member State must designate a single national regulatory authority at national level.131 There are limited exceptions for regional regulatory authorities.132 The exception could be relevant for Member States that are federal states.133

The regulatory authority must be independent. Its independence is safeguarded through organisational measures and constraints on the authority’s decision-making.134 Its staff and the persons responsible for its management must act independently from any market interests and must neither seek nor take direct instructions when carrying out the regulatory tasks.

The regulatory authority has a very broad range of duties.135 It fixes or approves transmission or distribution tariffs or their methodologies,136 ensures that electricity undertakings comply with their obligations under Community legislation, and has a large number of monitoring duties and information rights.

The regulatory authority can: issue binding decisions on electricity undertakings; require transmission and distribution system operators to modify terms and conditions to ensure that they are proportionate and applied in a non-discriminatory manner; and “decide upon and impose any necessary and proportionate measures to promote effective competition and ensure the proper functioning of the market”.

It can also “impose effective, proportionate and dissuasive penalties on electricity undertakings not complying with their obligations”, or propose that a competent court impose such penalties. This includes the power to “impose or propose the imposition of penalties of up to 10 % of the annual turnover”.137

The regulatory authority acts as a complaints and dispute settlement authority. Its decisions are binding. There may nevertheless be rights of appeal. In this case the decision has binding effect unless and until overruled on appeal.138

Decisions taken by the regulatory authority must be “fully reasoned and justified to allow for judicial review”.139 There must be “suitable mechanisms” at national level under which a party affected by a decision of a regulatory authority has a right of appeal to a body independent of the parties involved and of any government.140


Liberalisation and the Four Freedoms


One of the broad objectives of the three electricity packages was to contribute to an internal electricity market in which the so-called four freedoms apply.141 In practice, the four freedoms have been applied to foster the interests of retail consumers rather than the interests of electricity producers.


Benefits for Consumers

The electricity directives recognise that the free movement of goods, the freedom of establishment, and the freedom to provide services are rights guaranteed by the TFEU to EU citizens.142 It is assumed that these rights are achievable only in a “fully open market”. A fully open electricity market is a market that enables “all consumers freely to choose their suppliers and all suppliers freely to deliver to their customers”.143

This reflects the case-law of the CJEU according to which measures which hinder access to the market fall within the scope of the free movement of goods regardless of whether they are discriminatory or not.144

In addition to guaranteeing the four freedoms to EU citizens, the purpose of the internal market in electricity is to reduce costs, improve standards of service, and reduce risk. In particular, it tries to “achieve efficiency gains, competitive prices, and higher standards of service, and to contribute to security of supply and sustainability”.145

The benefits are to be achieved when electricity consumers and electricity firms use the freedoms guaranteed to them. The four freedoms are expected to result in “real choice” given to all electricity consumers, new business opportunities, and an increase in cross-border trade.146


No Producer Perspective

However, the focus is on the retail market and the consumer perspective rather than the wholesale market and the perspective of electricity producers. This is regardless of the fact that the role of the wholesale market is recognised147 and there are third-party access rights (TPA rights). There is no “fully open market” for producers. (a) While the electricity directives regulate “security of supply” for consumers, they fail to regulate security of consumption/off-take for electricity producers or suppliers. (b) The electricity directives do not ensure a level playing field for electricity producers. Different technologies are treated differently. Because of the preferential treatment of RES-E, the regulation of electricity markets makes it more difficult for electricity producers to find consumers depending on the Member State and the fuel or technology. These kinds of differences are likely to affect electricity trade between the Member States. (c) Pricing is regulated rather than free. The underlying assumption is that prices can “impair competition and proper functioning of the market”.148 The electricity directives are designed to limit prices paid by end consumers149 and not designed to enable wholesale market participants to profit from the market mechanism. Tampering with the market mechanism can have an adverse effect on investment in generation installations and increase electricity prices in the long run contrary to the stated objectives of the electricity directives.150 One of the proposed ways to address this problem is tampering with clearing prices in the day-ahead and intraday markets or “the introduction of harmonized maximum and minimum clearing prices that contribute to the strengthening of investment conditions”.151 (d) The broad scope of unbundling provisions can increase entry barriers (Sect. 3.5.6).

In principle, EU law should guarantee a level playing field in the internal market even for electricity producers by the prohibition of quantitative restrictions and measures having equivalent effect,152 by the regulation of state monopolies (such as state-owned TSOs),153 by the prohibition of state aid,154 and in other ways.


3.5.5 Effective Unbundling



General Remarks


The Third Electricity Directive requires “effective unbundling”. Effective unbundling means the “effective separation of networks from activities of generation and supply”.155 The effective unbundling regime applies to transmission. The unbundling regime applies even to distribution but not with its full force.156

The effective unbundling regime can hamper the business of a large electricity producer (or consumer) that has the financial means to invest in new transmission infrastructure. To illustrate, a large electricity producer could benefit from a new merchant interconnector as it could help to increase exports and influence prices in the price zones that the interconnector is connecting.157


Model


Effective unbundling should be effective in two respects according to the Directive. First, to “create incentives for the necessary investments” and “guarantee the access of new market entrants under a transparent and efficient regulatory regime”, it should be “effective in removing any conflict of interests between producers, suppliers and transmission system operators”. Second, it “should not create an overly onerous regulatory regime for national regulatory authorities”.158

The Third Electricity Directive provides for four forms of effective unbundling: ownership unbundling159; control unbundling; management unbundling; and the appointment of an independent operator. Moreover, Member States may choose between three unbundling regimes: Full Ownership Unbundling,160 Independent System Operator (ISO), and Independent Transmission Operator (ITO). (a) The standard model is Full Ownership Unbundling.161 It was nevertheless diluted162 due to resistance from France and Germany and because of an alleged conflict with the proportionality principle and the right to property.163 (b) The ISO is the alternative.164 Under the ISO model, a vertically integrated undertaking can retain ownership of the transmission network assets, provided that the operation of the network is assigned to a third party operator. At the same time, it loses most of its entrepreneurial rights.165 (c) The ITO is the second alternative.166


Distribution

The unbundling regime does not apply to distribution systems with its full force. There can be various categories of DSOs in this respect: DSOs that fall or do not fall within the scope of the unbundling regime; DSOs subject or not subject to ownership unbundling requirements; and DSOs subject or not subject to requirements as to the independence of organisation and decision-making.167 (a) A Member State may decide not to apply the regime to “integrated electricity undertakings serving less than 100,000 connected customers, or serving small isolated systems”.168 (b) There is no mandatory ownership unbundling for distribution assets under the Third Electricity Directive.169 (c) Where the distribution system operator is part of a vertically integrated undertaking, it must be “independent in terms of its organisation and decision-making from the other activities not related to distribution”.170

One may ask what happens when a vertically integrated public utility is divided into a generation entity and a distribution entity. Can the separated entities both be public utilities? Would it mean that these entities are part of the same legal entity? In the context of transmission, the public bodies exercising control over the two entities would have to be separate public bodies in order not to be regarded as the same person.171 This question may not always have been properly understood in the past.172


Third Countries

There is a stricter regime for transmission system owners or operators controlled by a person from a third country. The third country clause is also known as the Gazprom clause. The Member State will refuse authorisation unless it is demonstrated that the entity complies with the unbundling requirements and that “granting certification will not put at risk the security of energy supply of the Member State and the Community”.173


Ownership Unbundling


Unlike the management of the system, ownership unbundling would not be necessary for technical or operational reasons.174 It has other objectives. Ownership unbundling is regarded as necessary to remove “the incentive for vertically integrated undertakings to discriminate against competitors as regards network access and investment”.175

Ownership unbundling works in three ways. First, each undertaking which owns a transmission system must also act as a transmission system operator. Second, there are restrictions on that undertaking’s right to own a business that performs any of the functions of generation or supply.176 Third, there are similar restrictions on the rights of a firm that performs any of the functions of generation or supply to own a transmission business. (Control unbundling and borderline cases are discussed later in this section.)177

In other words, ownership unbundling implies “the appointment of the network owner as the system operator and its independence from any supply and production interests”.

In the US, the entities responsible for operating the transmission system are Independent System Operators (ISOs). While transmission system operations in the EU are managed by entities that own the transmission assets (TSOs), ISOs do not own transmission assets in the US.178


Control Unbundling


The control unbundling provisions of the Third Electricity Directive use the concepts of persons (that can be natural persons, public bodies,179 or undertakings180) and control (taken from the EC Merger Regulation181) and distinguish between two categories of undertakings: (1) the TSO/DSO or transmission/distribution system undertaking; and (2) the generation or supply undertaking. The unbundling provisions of the Third Directive seek to prevent relationships in which persons that exercise control over an undertaking belonging to one category exercise control or any right over an undertaking belonging to the other category.182

According to the wording of the Third Directive, one can distinguish between the exercising of control and the exercising of any right.183 For instance, the Member States are required to ensure that the same persons are not entitled to exercise control over a generation undertaking and, at the same time, exercise any right over a transmission system. Conversely, control over a transmission system operator should preclude the possibility of exercising control over a supply undertaking.


Control

While these rights have been defined in the Third Electricity Directive,184 the exercising of control has not been defined therein. The exercising of control is a broad concept.

Regardless of the recitals of the Third Electricity Directive,185 it is possible that control is not limited to the types of control mentioned in the EC Merger Regulation. There are two reasons for this. First, the definition of the term “any right” under the Third Electricity Directive resembles the definition of control under the EC Merger Regulation.186 This leaves the term control. The term control under the Third Directive should be given a meaning that makes it effective. Second, the EC Merger Regulation applies to the “concentration” of previously independent firms; concentration means change of control on a lasting basis.187 For the purposes of the Third Electricity Directive, however, it should not be relevant whether control is exercised on a lasting basis. For instance, structured contracts can provide control over generation or transmission assets for a limited period of time (Sect. 8.​2).

In the absence of any other party exercising control, an undertaking is de facto controlled by its management.188 A block of shares can also provide control. The size of the block depends on the firm. In practice, even a relatively small block of shares can provide control in large firms with a dispersed share ownership structure. There can thus be a controlling minority shareholding in many cases.189 On the other hand, a minority shareholding is not prohibited as such as it does not always provide control.190

In Finland, two generating companies (Fortum and Pohjolan Voima) were shareholders of the TSO (Fingrid). The regulator took steps to implement the new unbundling requirements. Fortum and Pohjolan Voima therefore divested their holding in Fingrid to the State of Finland and Ilmarinen, a mutual pension insurance company, in April 2011. After the transaction, Fingrid’s shares were held by the State of Finland and institutional investors.191


Rights

The rights mean here (a) voting rights; (b) the power to appoint members of the supervisory board, the administrative board, or bodies legally representing the undertaking; or (c) rights attached to a majority share.192 For instance, a person can hold a minority block of shares in an undertaking that belongs to the other category (provided that the person does not control that undertaking in other ways).

The wording of the Directive implies that the provisions on ownership unbundling do not prevent an undertaking belonging to one category (rather than a party controlling it) from having a non-controlling minority shareholding in an undertaking belonging to the other category.193


Borderline cases of ownership and control unbundling


Borderline cases can be illustrated with various customary sources of funding and the case of merchant lines.


Financial Investors

One of the objectives of effective unbundling is to “create incentives for the necessary investments”.194 Investments must be funded in one way or another. Obviously, it would be contrary to the stated purpose of effective unbundling to hamper infrastructure investments by restricting system operators’ access to funding.

Now, infrastructure investments are customarily funded by specialised and institutional investors that are likely to have invested in other energy projects as well. Whether they are permitted to provide the necessary funding can depend on the interpretation of the unbundling provisions.


Block of Shares

How small should a block of shares be before it does not provide “control”? The question is relevant, because an institutional investor may have invested in the shares of an electricity producer in, say, Sweden and may want to subscribe for shares in a system operator in, say, Germany. Infrastructure investment will be hampered, if the threshold of “control” is low.

The Commission has clarified its practice in a staff working document.195 Generally, the Commission does not want to refuse certification of a TSO “in cases where it can be clearly demonstrated that there is no incentive for a shareholder in a TSO to influence the TSO’s decision making to favour his generation, production and/or supply interest to the detriment of other network users”.

The Commission identified two main forms. The first was geographic separation of activities. In certain situations, “it was evident from the facts of the concrete case that the simultaneous participation in transmission activities on the one hand, and in generation, production and/or supply activities on the other hand, did not give rise to any potential conflict of interest or incentive to exploit it, and as a consequence did not in any way risk to impact negatively on the independent management of the TSO. This was for instance the case where a shareholder had a participation in a transmission network in the EU, as well as a participation in generation activities in the United States or in Australia, with no connection or interface between the energy systems concerned”.

The second related to the circumstances of financial investors: “For financial investors, ownership unbundled TSOs form an important class of potential investment opportunities, taking into account that investments in transmission infrastructure with regulated network tariffs offer stable, low risk returns that fit well with their investment profile. Cooperation with financial investors may enable ownership unbundled TSOs to raise the necessary funds for the capital expenditure that is needed to realise the investments in the EU energy network infrastructure. In situations as referred to above, where it can be clearly demonstrated that even though one or more of the circumstances referred to in Article 9(1)(b), (c) and/or (d) appear to be present, there is clearly no incentive for a shareholder in a TSO to influence the decision making in this TSO with the intention to favour its generation, production and/or supply interests to the detriment of other network users, the Commission has taken the view that a refusal to certify such a TSO given the fact that such participation in generation, production and/or supply activities does not lead to a situation which the unbundling rules seek to prevent”.


Leasing

Can other forms of funding provide control? One of the ways for a firm to finance its activities is to use somebody else’s assets. To illustrate, the system operator does not have to raise other external funding to the extent that it can use assets owned by somebody else under a leasing agreement.196 The question is when the ownership of transmission assets can be regarded as ownership of a transmission “system” and to what extent the ownership of a transmission system requires the ownership of transmission assets.

For instance, there are no requirements for ownership unbundling of DSOs in Finland. At the end of 2012, 9 DSOs operated a distribution network leased from their parent company. Other DSOs used some network assets such as substations under a lease contract.197


Merchant Lines

Ownership unbundling raises even some questions relating to merchant lines. Investment in merchant lines could increase transmission capacity. However, the Third Electricity Directive does not recognise operators of merchant lines as such. This can hamper investment.

The Directive applies to “electricity undertakings”. This broad category includes even owners or operators of merchant lines regardless of how merchant lines are defined.198 According to the terminology of the Directive, the functional equivalent of a merchant line could be an “interconnector”, that is, equipment used to link electricity systems199 (rather than a “direct line”200).

However, the owner of transmission assets such as interconnectors should be a TSO. This seems reasonable in the light of the fact that an interconnector is similar to a simple transmission network in the physical sense. On the other hand, the function of an interconnector may also be close to a generation facility201 and a TSO has more functions compared with the necessary functions of the operator of a merchant line.202

Neither Regulation 1228/2003 nor Regulation 714/2009 mentions merchant lines. There can be interconnectors that are owned by a natural or legal person separate from the system operators in whose systems the interconnector is built.203 That person can be a system operator.204


Management Unbundling


The provisions on ownership and control unbundling are complemented by provisions on management unbundling. The same person should (a) neither be a member of the managing boards of undertakings belonging to different categories (b) nor be entitled to appoint members of the managing boards of an undertaking belonging to one category and exercise control or any right over an undertaking belonging to the other category205 (or such a firm in the gas market206). (c) Moreover, staff of a transmission system operator which was part of a vertically integrated undertaking must not be transferred to undertakings performing any of the functions of generation and supply.207 (d) It is also prohibited to transfer commercially sensitive information from a transmission system operator to a generation or supply undertaking.208 On the other hand, the latter are bound to transfer such information to the TSO in the course of normal operations.


The Appointment of an Independent Operator


The main form of effective unbundling is complemented by one or two exceptions. The Third Electricity Directive does not necessarily force vertically integrated undertakings to sell their transmission networks. An undertaking that was a vertically integrated undertaking on 3 September 2009 could maintain its ownership of a transmission network provided that the undertaking set up an independent transmission operator which is independent from the supply and generation interests of the vertically integrated undertaking.209 The appointment of an independent operator requires a proposal by the vertically integrated undertaking, approval by the Member State’s regulatory authority, and approval by the Commission.210 An independent operator must be monitored even by the Member State’s competition authorities.211 The Third Electricity Directive lays down a detailed framework for the operation of independent system operators.212

Alternatively, the Member States may use methods that are more effective in guaranteeing the independence of the transmission system operator.213 However, this can only be a rare exception in the light of the stringent requirements that independent system operators must fulfil.


Unbundling and Extraterritorial Effect


In principle, the unbundling provisions of the Third Electricity Directive do not have extraterritorial effect. One may nevertheless ask whether the scope of unbundling provisions is limited to the same Member State in which the transmission system operator operates or whether the regulatory authority of a Member State must take into account activities in other Member States or third countries as well. For instance, may an electricity company operate a transmission system in one Member State and generate electricity in another Member State or a third country?

In practice, the unbundling provisions of the Third Electricity Directive do have extraterritorial effect. The scope of the unbundling provisions is not limited to activities in the same Member State. The operation or control of a transmission system located in a Member State is a restricted activity and reserved only for persons that fulfil the unbundling requirements—regardless of whether these persons are EU companies, citizens of the EU, or from third countries.214 One could say that “fully effective separation of network activities from supply and generation activities should apply throughout the Community to both Community and non-Community undertakings”.215

The broad scope of unbundling provisions could raise some legal concerns. First, the broad scope of unbundling provisions could make it more difficult for electricity companies from other Member States or third countries to enter the market contrary to the main objectives of the electricity directives—and the four freedoms. Second, neither the Third Electricity Directive nor the national provisions of Member States’ laws may restrict freedom of establishment for firms established in a Member State. Third, the broad scope unbundling provisions could increase entry barriers for electricity companies from third countries, and the Community may have international obligations relating to market entry.216

For this reason, the Commission may give an opinion on certification in relation to a transmission system owner or a transmission system operator which is controlled by a person or persons from a third country or third countries.217


3.5.6 Network Codes


Network codes play a very important role in structuring electricity markets. Each electricity network must operate according to certain common rules because of technical reasons and network security. In the past, there was a different set of rules for each country. The internal electricity market requires common rules for many countries.

The need for common rules was addressed by Regulation 714/2009 that lays down a mechanism to adopt network codes for transactions with a cross-border impact.218 A network code has the same status as a European Regulation and is directly applicable in all EU Member States. A network code takes precedence over domestic law. Network codes can be preceded by ACER’s framework guidelines that set out principles for developing them.219

Common network codes are developed for cross-border network issues and market integration issues. They are without prejudice to the Member States’ right to establish national network codes which do not affect cross-border trade.220 National network codes will continue to exist.221

The CACM Regulation is the first of the ten EU network codes developed in accordance with the Third Energy Package. Member States voted to adopt the CACM Regulation on 5 December 2014. It was preceded by ENTSO-E Network Code for Capacity Allocation and Congestion Management (final draft of 27 September 2012) that was based on ACER Framework Guidelines.222 The Commission chose to call the CACM Regulation a guideline regulation instead of a network code. ENTSO-E began to use the term “guideline” or “binding guideline” for this network code after the 20–21 May 2014 Florence Forum.223

After CACM, the Network Code for Requirements for Generators (NC RfG) became the second network code to enter Comitology, the process by which they will become law.

Obviously, implementing ten new network codes (or guideline regulations) increases the complexity of the regulatory framework and market participants’ exposure to legal risk.


3.6 Competition Law



3.6.1 General Remarks


After the electricity directives, the second area of sectoral legislation that will be discussed here is competition law. Competition law has a role to play in electricity markets due to the existence of natural monopolies, national champions, other large electricity producers that used to be vertically integrated firms, and long-term contracts.224 In addition, EU competition law has played an important role in the regulation of the electricity markets, because it has been easier for the Commission to apply competition law than sectoral regulation. The role of competition law has diminished with the increasing size of the sector-specific regulatory regime and the growing use of electricity exchanges and auctions.


The Market, Structural Remedies

Electricity wholesale markets are, to a large extent, national or regional. Electricity flows between different Member States are limited by congestion on cross-border interconnectors. While the existence of price differences between different markets can be explained by congestion, cross-border electricity flows cannot be explained by the existence of price differences between markets.225

After the second legislative package, the European Commission launched sector inquiries into the functioning of the European electricity markets (and gas markets). The Commission’s sector inquiry is a point of reference for many legislative developments in the energy sector and some national competition authorities have launched their own sector inquiries.226 The Commission’s 2007 final report on the sector inquiry identified the essential features of the European electricity markets:



  • Transport activities remain regulated, because they are a natural monopoly. Generation, wholesale trading, and retail supply have been progressively opened to competition.227


  • Third party access to the network is essential.228


  • The price elasticity of electricity demand is very low over the short term.229


  • The use of different fuels results in different cost structures. This influences price formation on short term electricity markets as the price is based on short-term marginal costs.230


  • Balancing markets tend to be more concentrated than the underlying wholesale markets, because balancing requires additional technical characteristics of plants.231


  • There are various market structures and various business models in the EU. Business strategies are more diverse in areas that were liberalised earlier. Vertically integrated companies, or very strong ownership and/or contractual links between generators and suppliers, are predominant in more recently liberalised Member States.232


  • Electricity markets are vulnerable to the exercise of market power.233

The Commission’s 2007 final report on the sector inquiry also identified the following deficiencies:



  • market concentration was high at the wholesale level234;


  • there were high barriers to entry (such as the foreclosure of downstream markets, an insufficient level of unbundling, insufficient cross-border capacities, and balancing regimes that favoured incumbents);


  • existing network capacities were largely controlled by incumbent companies (as a result, there were information asymmetries between incumbents and market entrants, and incumbents had an incentive not to expand network capacities for the benefit of market entrants);


  • there was foreclosure of downstream markets (caused by an insufficient level of unbundling, long contract durations, the lack of competitive offers from non-incumbent suppliers, and restrictive practices in relation to the operation of supply contracts);


  • there was a lack of efficient and transparent price formation; and


  • balancing regimes were often found to favour incumbents.

While some of these deficiencies can be addressed by competition law, others require regulatory and structural measures. The Commission acknowledged that regulatory and structural measures were necessary for tackling the insufficient unbundling of networks, gaps in the regulatory environment regarding cross-border trade, the lack of liquidity in electricity wholesale markets, and the general lack of transparency in market operations.

This contributed to the adoption of the third legislative package in 2009. In other words, sector-specific regulation was recognised as the most important tool.

However, the Commission would have preferred clearer unbundling rules than the complicated rules adopted in the Third Electricity Directive. Because the Third Electricity Directive does not prevent the Commission from applying EU competition law, the Commission has an incentive to use general competition law to achieve the intended result.


Lower Threshold to Use EU Competition Law

It is easier for the Commission to use general competition law than sector-specific regulation.

To begin with, the sector-specific regulation of electricity markets is secondary EU law primarily applied by national energy regulators. The Commission’s powers in the energy markets are limited to its general powers.235 There is no single European energy regulator to control the markets. Unlike the sector-specific regulation of electricity markets, EU competition law is Treaty law that can be applied by the Commission (in addition to national competition authorities and courts236 that apply even national competition law237). The Commission is the regulatory authority by virtue of the TFEU.238

The Commission does act as the regulatory authority in many cases239 and the Agency for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators (ACER) in some cases240 under the Third Electricity Directive. However, one may ask whether the Commission’s enforcement powers fall within the scope of the TEU and the TFEU in the light of the wording of the Treaties. The Third Electricity Directive was based on Treaty provisions on the mutual recognition of qualifications, freedom to provide services, and the approximation of laws. None of the Treaty provisions referred to in the Third Electricity Directive can be used as a basis for making the Commission a regulatory authority that exercises powers in relation to individual market participants ex ante.241 The administrative powers that the TFEU vests in the Commission are powers exercised in relation to Member States ex post.242

The Commission also has an incentive to resort to competition law. On one hand, there is no single European energy regulator to control energy markets. On the other, the Commission has wide powers to enforce competition law, the Commission has an opportunity to do so in the light of the existence of monopolies and long-term contracts in electricity markets,243 the assessment of market power depends on how the Commission defines the market,244 and there is a well-developed body of competition law in the EU.

One of the drawbacks with the application of competition law is that the best way to tackle the issues may not be ex-post investigations. The application of competition law is combined with a high level of uncertainty and legal risk. It can be time-consuming and difficult to assess the positive and negative effects of contract practices.245


Complementary Regime

Competition law does not reduce the Commission’s other powers, and the scope of EU competition law is not limited by the scope of sector-specific regulation. EU competition law and sector-specific regulation are complementary rather than mutually exclusive. The Commission can assess the case from a competition law perspective even where the issue is governed by sector-specific regulation.

In Deutsche Telekom, the Court of First Instance found that that the scope of Article 102 TFEU is not affected by the scope of sector-specific regulation applied by Member States’ national authorities.246

There is a difference between EU competition aw and US antitrust law. While EU competition law has a very broad scope, the scope of the application of US antitrust law is constrained by sector-specific legislation according to the ruling of the US Supreme Court in Verizon v. Trinko.247

The Trinko ruling suggests that sector-specific remedies are the primary remedies where they are available. Moreover, it marks the recognition of a “pre-emption” or “exhaustion” principle in the field of antitrust. Where a sector-specific remedy exists, private claims on the basis of antitrust rules should be exhausted. The US Supreme Court’s reasoning is based on costs/benefits arguments. When a regulatory structure has been set up to reduce and remedy the risks of a competitive harm, the additional benefits from antitrust enforcement are likely to be limited according to the court.248


Constraints

There are constraints on the application of EU competition law. The constraints relate to the subjective scope of the prohibitions (the addressees of the rules) and proportionality.

EU competition law can only prohibit behaviour for which one or more undertakings are responsible (EDP, Deutsche Telekom).249 As EU competition law applies to undertakings but sector-specific regulation is addressed to Member States, the relevant issue is who is responsible for the anti-competitive behaviour. EU competition law cannot prohibit undertakings from taking action necessary for the purpose of complying with sector-specific regulation, and it cannot prohibit acts for which the regulator is responsible. The fact that EU competition law and sector-specific regulation are not addressed to the same parties can, in effect, act as a constraint on the application of EU competition law without limiting its scope as such.

In EDP, the Court of First Instance considered the relationship between the EC Merger Regulation and the Second Gas Directive. In some cases, the creation or strengthening of a dominant position may in itself have the consequence that competition is significantly impeded, in which case a concentration cannot be permitted.250 In EDP, however, the absence of effective competition was caused by national and Community legislation. According to the Court of First Instance, “[u]ndertakings cannot be criticised for significantly impeding effective competition where that competition does not exist as a result of national and Community legislation”.251

In Deutsche Telekom, a case on the abuse of a dominant position, the relevant issue was who was responsible for pricing. The charges were approved in advance by the regulatory authority.252 On the other hand, an undertaking in a dominant position may have a special responsibility to submit applications for adjustment of its charges.253 The question was thus who was responsible for the anti-competitive behaviour.254

In addition, the application of competition law is constrained by the general principle of proportionality. Measures adopted by Community institutions must not exceed what is appropriate and necessary for attaining the objective pursued. Where there is a choice between several appropriate measures, the least onerous measure must be used.255 There are even other constraints such as constraints relating to the use of structural remedies.


3.6.2 Structural Remedies


The main rule is that EU competition law provides for behavioural rather than structural remedies. Article 101 TFEU prohibits restrictive agreements and similar practices between undertakings rather than the existence of market structures that are not effective. Article 102 prohibits the abuse of a dominant position rather than its mere existence. Structural remedies can nevertheless be based on the EC Merger Regulation, Regulation 1/2003, and the case-law of the CJEU.


The EC Merger Regulation

The EC Merger Regulation applies to concentrations defined as qualified changes of control.256 It applies to significant and lasting structural changes—such as mergers and acquisitions and joint ventures—with a Community dimension.257 It does not apply to the mere existence of market structures even where the market structures impede effective competition.258 In change of control situations, however, the Commission has plenty of discretion to apply structural remedies ex ante and ex post.

There is a duty to notify concentrations before they are implemented.259 Whether a concentration that falls within the scope of the EC Merger Regulation is permitted or not depends on whether the concentration is “compatible with the common market”.260 The participating undertakings may enter into commitments vis-à-vis the Commission to make the concentration “compatible with the common market”, and the Commission may attach to its decision conditions and obligations intended to ensure that the undertakings comply with the commitments.261

The Commission may take structural measures even where a concentration has been implemented without the Commission’s consent or the commitments are not complied with.262 Where a concentration has not been notified in advance, the Commission may analyse it and declare it incompatible with the common market if it does not fulfill the statutory criteria.263 Subject to the principle of proportionality,264 the Commission may order any appropriate measure to ensure that the undertakings concerned dissolve the concentration or take other restorative measures as required in its decision.265 It is expressly stated in the Regulation that the Commission may order the dissolution of the merger or the disposal of all the shares or assets acquired to restore the situation prevailing prior to the implementation of the concentration.

The Commission has applied structural remedies in a number of electricity market cases under Article 8 of the Merger Regulation.266

In EDP/ENI/GDP, the Commission declared a concentration incompatible with the common market.267

In EDF/EnBW,268 the Commission declared a concentration compatible with the common market subject to compliance with extensive commitments. To illustrate, EnBW (Energie Baden-Württemberg AG) agreed to divest its shareholding in WATT AG (an electricity company in Switzerland), in which it held 24.5 % of the voting stock.

Structural remedies were used also in Gaz de France/Suez. To illustrate, Gaz de France agreed to divest its stake in SPE (a company that is present in the Belgian electricity and natural gas markets and provides energy services).269

The threshold of “control” is rather low according to the practice of the Commission. Even a minority holding may suffice. A low threshold of control increases the number of concentrations that fall within the scope of the EC Merger Regulation270 and makes EU merger control more restrictive.

In Gaz de France/Suez, a supply company (Suez) held 27.45 % of the shares in a Belgian electricity TSO (Elia).271 The Commission was of the opinion that the supply company could exercise control or significant influence over the transmission company in the circumstances of the case.272


Regulation 1/2003

The use of general competition law for unbundling purposes is made easier by Regulation 1/2003 that empowers the Commission to apply not only behavioural but even structural remedies.273

While the EC Merger Regulation has a limited scope (it applies to transactions that bring about lasting changes of control and have a Community dimension), the scope of Regulation 1/2003 is much wider. Regulation 1/2003 covers other situations that fall within the scope of general EU competition law.

While it is easiest for the Commission to apply structural remedies when undertakings offer commitments, the Commission does not have unlimited discretion. The commitments accepted by the Commission must be necessary and sufficient to address the concerns identified by the Commission and not disproportionate.274

Most competition law commitments are behavioural rather than structural. For policy reasons,275 structural commitments were used in some energy cases—E.ON, RWE, ENI—in which the Commission forced energy firms to unbundle ownership.

In two E.ON cases,276 the Commission made structural commitments binding on an undertaking in the German electricity wholesale market and the balancing market. In the first case, the Commission had concerns that E.ON might have withdrawn available generation capacity from the German wholesale electricity markets to raise prices, and deterred investments in energy generation by competitors. In the second case, the Commission had concerns that the transmission subsidiary of E.ON might have favoured its production affiliate for providing balancing services, while passing the resulting costs on to final consumers, and prevented power producers from other Member States from exporting balancing energy into its transmission zone. E.ON offered to divest around 5,000 MW of its generation capacity to address the concerns regarding the wholesale market. E.ON also committed to divest its extra-high voltage network to meet the concerns on the electricity balancing market.277

In RWE,278 the Commission applied structural commitments in the German natural gas market. The Commission had concerns that RWE might have abused its dominant position on the gas transmission market. To address these concerns, RWE committed to divest its existing Western German high-pressure transmission network to an independent purchaser, the acquisition by whom would not give rise to prima facie competition concerns.279

In the ENI case,280 the Commission believed that ENI infringed Article 102 TFEU when it managed and operated its natural gas transmission pipelines. ENI committed to divest its transmission business. According to the Commission, the commitments were necessary and sufficient to address the concerns identified by the Commission and not disproportionate.281

In practice, the Commission has plenty of discretion to determine whether the commitments are proportionate or not.282


3.6.3 Foreclosure



General Remarks


Many electricity cases relate to foreclosure. The Commission’s 2007 final report on the sector inquiry identified foreclosure as one of the deficiencies of European electricity markets. Generally, one can distinguish between horizontal and vertical foreclosure. Both can consist of other than price-based exclusion and price-based exclusion.283


Horizontal Foreclosure

Horizontal foreclosure looks different in the context of electricity markets because of the physical characteristics of electricity. There are four important causes of foreclosure here: restriction of access to transmission networks (Chap. 5); vertical integration of network and supply activities (such as complete vertical integration or the integration of generation and distribution, Sect. 2.​3.​5); vertical integration of generation and retail (so-called integrated firms, Sect. 2.​3.​5); and exclusive long-term contracts (Chap. 8). They give rise to two forms of foreclosure: infrastructure foreclosure and market foreclosure.


Infrastructure Foreclosure

Infrastructure foreclosure means the lack of access to electricity networks on transparent and non-discriminatory conditions. Restriction of access to transmission networks is a form of infrastructure foreclosure. Vertical integration of network and supply activities (complete vertical integration) increases the risk of infrastructure foreclosure. As European electricity markets cannot be opened up without network access, infrastructure foreclosure is something that the Commission and national competition authorities have focused on.


Market Foreclosure

There are two forms of market foreclosure: vertical integration of generation and retail; and exclusive long-term contracts.

The Commission has investigated market foreclosure as alleged breaches of Article 102 TFEU. The investigated cases include: the limitation of transport capacities through refusal to deal or underinvestment; and market foreclosure through long-term supply or transmission capacity contracts.

In practice, it could be difficult to apply Article 101 TFEU to market foreclosure. Market foreclosure is often caused by the existence of market structures that are not effective, but Article 101 TFEU does not prohibit the existence of any particular market structure as such (for Article 102 TFEU, see Sect. 3.7.2).


Restriction of Access to Transmission Networks

There are three main forms of restricting access to transmission networks.

First, a TSO may have an incentive to abuse its natural monopoly.284

In Svenska Kraftnät, the issue was whether the Swedish electricity TSO had curtailed export transmission capacity on Swedish interconnectors to neighbouring countries. The curtailment of export transmission capacity means that domestically generated or imported electricity is reserved for domestic consumption contrary to the objective of creating an internal market for electricity.285 Svenska Kraftnät offered commitments that enabled it to manage congestion in the Swedish transmission system without limiting trading capacity on interconnectors, and commitments designed to reduce congestion.286

Second, a vertically integrated undertaking may have an incentive to restrict access to its transmission network to use the transmission capacity itself. The Commission has investigated such situations in the light of Article 102 TFEU in both gas287 and electricity markets.288

Third, the existence of long-term contracts for the use of transmission capacity can lead to infrastructure foreclosure (this issue is discussed in the context of market foreclosure through long-term contracts).


Vertical Integration of Network and Supply Activities


Vertical integration of network and supply activities (complete vertical integration) increases the risk of infrastructure foreclosure. Preventing competitors from having access to infrastructure necessary for competing in upstream or downstream markets may amount to abuse of a dominant position (Article 102 TFEU).


Essential Facilities

The Commission has applied principles developed under the concept of essential facilities. The first time the Commission used this concept explicitly was in Sea Containers/Stena Sealink.289

The essential facilities doctrine was imported to the EU from the US as a legal transplant. It first appeared in the US290 as a limitation to the main competition law rule that businesses may choose their contract parties (the Colgate doctrine).291 The essential facilities doctrine is used to impose on owners of essential facilities a duty to deal with competitors. However, the essential facilities doctrine is nowadays regarded as a flawed means of deciding whether a unilateral, unconditional refusal to deal harms competition in the US.292 The relevance of the essential facilities doctrine was reduced by the Trinko case.293

In Trinko, the Supreme Court declined to find a duty to deal. The Supreme Court argued: “Firms may acquire monopoly power by establishing an infrastructure that renders them uniquely suited to serve their customers. Compelling such firms to share the source of their advantage is in some tension with the underlying purpose of antitrust law, since it may lessen the incentive for the monopolist, the rival, or both to invest in those economically beneficial facilities. Enforced sharing also requires antitrust courts to act as central planners, identifying the proper price, quantity, and other terms of dealing—a role for which they are ill suited. Moreover, compelling negotiation between competitors may facilitate the supreme evil of antitrust: collusion. Thus, as a general matter, the Sherman Act ‘does not restrict the long recognized right of [a] trader or manufacturer engaged in an entirely private business, freely to exercise his own independent discretion as to parties with whom he will deal’”.294

On the other hand, the Supreme Court stated that the right to refuse to deal with rivals is not “unqualified”. The Court reserved the possibility that a refusal to cooperate with rivals can constitute anticompetitive conduct and violate §2 of the Sherman Act “[u]nder certain circumstances”.295

The European Court of Justice has dealt with refusals to deal in various cases after Commercial Solvents.296 Unlike the European Commission, however, the CJEU has not used the term “essential facilities”. In Bronner, the plaintiff argued that the essential facilities doctrine was established under the case-law of the CJEU,297 but the CJEU refused to use the concept of essential facilities. In addition, the CJEU restricted the scope of the duty to deal.298

In Bronner, it was not sufficient that the undertaking had a dominant position. The wording of Article 102 TFEU does not prohibit a dominant undertaking from doing things internally as a vertically integrated firm. An undertaking has a right to provide a service or refuse to do so even when it has a dominant position—subject to general competition law constraints such as the rule that a dominant undertaking may not use “methods different from those that condition normal competition” (Hoffmann-La Roche).299

The exercise of this right by a dominant undertaking may, in exceptional circumstances, constitute an abuse.300 According to judgment of the CJEU in Bronner, there are such exceptional circumstances where: (1) the service in itself is “indispensable” to carrying on the other party’s business because there is “no actual or potential substitute in existence” for the requested service; (2) the refusal to provide the service would be “likely to eliminate all competition” in the market on the part of the person requesting the service; and (3) the refusal would be “incapable of being objectively justified”.301 In effect, the test laid down by the CJEU in Bronner prohibits the monopolisation of the market in a way that resembles §2 of the Sherman Act after Trinko but has a broader scope. Because the test is an objective one, it is not necessary to consider intent in the EU.302


Strategic Underinvestment

An alternative approach could be the doctrine of strategic underinvestment.303 The prevailing view is that a dominant undertaking may have a duty to deal under the essential facilities doctrine under some circumstances, but no duty under Article 102 TFEU to expand existing facilities or construct new ones to improve market entry. The Commission seemed to share this view in its 2009 Guidance on Article 82 of the EC Treaty (now Article 102 TFEU).304 In ENI, however, the Commission indicated that there could be such an obligation, and investment commitments were used in Gaz de France/Suez.305

In ENI, the Commission discussed the relationship between the essential facilities doctrine and strategic underinvestment. If the holder of an essential facility has a dominant position and its capacities are fully used, it has, according to the Commission, an obligation to “take all possible measures to remove the constraints imposed by the lack of capacity and to organise its business in a manner that makes a maximum amount of capacity of the essential facility available”.306 The Commission identified the strategic limitation of investment as one of the competitive concerns of ENI’s alleged refusal to supply strategy.307 As the concerns were cleared when ENI divested its essential facility (transport business),308 it was not necessary for ENI to offer any investment commitments.

Gaz de France/Suez was a merger control case. A study by the CREG (Belgium’s Commission for Electricity and Gas Regulation) found a persistent state of (contractual) congestion on the Belgian gas transmission network caused by inadequate investment.309 According to the Commission, the proposed merger would have discouraged investment.310 The parties undertook to make a series of investments to increase Belgian and French gas infrastructure capacity.311

The power to establish and enforce investment obligations would be problematic. One may ask whether Article 102 TFEU should vest such powers in competition authorities.312 First, the interpretation of Article 102 is constrained not only by the principle of proportionality313 but also by the right to property and the freedom to conduct a business.314 Second, it would be very difficult for outsiders such as judges or competition authorities to take rational investment decisions on behalf of the undertakings concerned. The perceived quality of investment decisions depends on very subjective preferences on what should be done (strategy), cash flow (return), and risk, and on the quality of available information. Judges or competition authorities are not better equipped to take investment decisions. For instance, this explains the business judgment rule in company law.315 Third, the obligation to invest would be likely to cement the dominant position.


Vertical Integration of Generation and Retail


Vertical integration of generation and retail reduces the need to trade on wholesale markets. For the vertically integrated firm, this may bring benefits.316

The vertical integration of generation and retail is not prohibited by the electricity directives. The purpose of the Third Electricity Directive is, among other things, to make retail activities easier for electricity producers. The electricity directives should, according to their stated objectives, reduce obstacles to the sale of electricity to wholesale and retail customers,317 facilitate the right to choose the supplier,318 and increase price competition between suppliers.319 The vertical integration of generation and retail is thus assumed to increase competition between producers.

However, vertical integration reduces the liquidity of wholesale markets.320 If all electricity producers had their own retail businesses, there would be hardly any room for independent suppliers whose business does not include generation, because independent suppliers would have limited access to uncommitted generation. As a result of the absence of independent suppliers, it would be more difficult for independent electricity producers to supply electricity directly to the wholesale market.321 Moreover, unlike the various distribution channels in sale of goods, electricity distribution is a natural monopoly.

The Third Electricity Directive addresses this issue in two ways. (a) Effective unbundling is designed to ensure that independent electricity producers can supply electricity to end consumers who may choose their suppliers.322 (b) From 1 July 2007, all customers have been regarded as “eligible customers” who may choose their own suppliers.323 The supplier may be a local one or established in any Member State of the EU,324 and distribution system operators must not discriminate between system users.325

However, the Third Electricity Directive requires the effective unbundling of generation and transmission rather than the separation of generation and distribution activities.326 The unbundling rules apply to distribution in a diluted form because the rules do not require ownership unbundling.327 Moreover, while the Third Directive facilitates “non-discriminatory network access”, it does not facilitate a level playing field for electricity producers regardless of their generation technology (Sect. 3.7.7).


Exclusive Long-Term Contracts


Exclusive long-term contracts can lead to market foreclosure, because a party that commits to deal exclusively with its contract party has no need to deal with anyone else. Contracts that have vertical foreclosure as their purpose or effect can infringe Articles 101 or 102 TFEU.


Exclusive Long-Term Supply Contracts

In principle, long-term supply contracts could be the cause of vertical foreclosure as their effects can be similar to vertical integration.328 The Third Electricity Directive provides that the Member States should encourage the use of interruptible supply contracts.329

In practice, however, Article 101 TFEU is not applied to vertical agreements to the extent that they do not contain prohibited clauses.330 Moreover, long contract duration can often be regarded as compatible with competition law because of its benefits. It is particularly interesting that long-term contracts can increase infrastructure investments by reducing investment risk and by making it easier to raise funding. The benefits of long-term contracts have been recognised in EU competition law.

They were recognised by the Commission in Scottish Nuclear

Only gold members can continue reading. Log In or Register to continue